Cost-shifting
The examples and perspective in this article may not represent a worldwide view of the subject. (April 2021) |
Cost-shifting[1] is either an economic situation where one individual, group, or government underpays for a service, resulting another individual, group or government overpaying for a service (shifting compared to expected burden).[2][3] It can occur where one group pays a smaller share of costs than before, resulting in another group paying a larger share of costs than before (shifting compared to previous arrangement). Some commentators on health policy in the United States believe the former currently happens in Medicare and Medicaid as they underpay for services resulting in private insurers overpaying.[4]
In 1995, Health Affairs started a study testing the "cost-shifting" theory using a unique new data set that combines MarketScan private claims data with Medicare hospital cost reports, the study ran from 1995–2009. In May 2013 when the findings were released, the study found that a 10 percent reduction in Medicare payment rates led to an estimated reduction in private payment rates of 3 percent or 8 percent, depending on the statistical model used. These payment rate spillovers may reflect an effort by hospitals to rein in their operating costs in the face of lower Medicare payment rates.[5]
Cost shifting in Healthcare[]
This section needs additional citations for verification. (April 2021) |
Cost shifting can mean many different things. It can mean a situation where different groups are charged different prices. Or it can mean a situation where a group underpays for some services. But in the end, it is a situation, where the cost does not really equal the service.[6]
Some examples of cost shifting are for example; in America the commercial insurers pay the hospitals more than the Medicare. Some organisations are even charged less than health insurers.
Problems of Cost shifting in Health care[]
The problem of cost shifting in health care is based on the fact that Medicare pays hospitals only a fraction of the patient's costs, which is often significantly lower than the replacement cost.
The government[which?] says that this gap (the cost gap between the patient’s real cost and the compensation), is because the compensation is paying only for the costs of the treatment (meaning, it pays the doctors and hospital for the expenses).
Situation in 10s[]
Cost shifting has been discussed for a long time. It is still assumed to be one of controversial topics[7] in USA healthcare politics. There are studies, which try to clarify why and where in the system this phenomenon originates. Researchers try to provide facts and studies[7] to explain how private payers are charged more in response to shortfalls in public payments and so partly pay for state insured payers.
Cost shifting is a situation in which people may pay for the same goods or services at different prices. One of the biggest known examples[7] is in the US healthcare system. Few causes could be that in the USA the health insurance is not obligatory, or there exist more systems of insurance. Workers are usually insured by their employer. However, the most people are state-insured[8] by state insurance programs Medicare and Medicaid. Because of multiple insurance system and other factors (such as deals between insurers and hospitals and so on), a subsidy system which supports the healthcare in the USA. On one side are sited regular insurance payers who could subsidize healthcare for the other insured patience. On the other are people, who are state insured because they cannot afford any other kind of insurance. Cost-shifting is caused by some reasons mentioned in following paragraphs.
Cost-cutting as a cause of cost-shifting[]
Cost-shifting is a situation where one group of payers overpays costs for a good or a service for another group, which in total pays less than the first one.
This problem originates in hospitals. They need to pay for treatment and staff performing it. Hospitals need to balance their costs and incomes. Problem begins in communication between hospitals and insurers, who want to save as much money as possible. Therefore, hospitals cannot charge their patients higher prices. If they did, it could lead to terminating a contract between hospital and insurer and moving a patient into a different hospital.[7][9]
Further there are public programs such as Medicare and Medicate, which are limited by law.
Main reason is that revenue from state insured patients is lower than from private insured patients.[7]
From that reason hospitals and healthcare facilities could be forced to come to cost cutting or cross-subsidization, in order to balance their incomes and expenditures. That means that they for example charge private insurance for additional treatment, which was never did, because they need to obtain more money from private insurer. On of possible solutions could be deficit, which is not in long terms sustainable. Mendoza states that small deficit could be caused by revenue deficit, caused by change of insurer by payers, or by third-party payer, who refuses to pay the whole amount of money for his insured member. This situation could happen mainly with costs unrelated to a treatment.[7]
Cost shifting is assumed to be present in medical facilities with a higher rate of state insured patients. According to the source[7] there are studies which presents a development of differences in payments between private and public insurers. It suggests that Medicare and Medicaid payment reductions could cause significantly lower profits and so started cost cutting in hospitals necessary to avoid closing hospitals.[7]
According to the study written by Roger Lee Mendoza[7] there could be assumed some discrimination premises which may lead to cost shifting:
- Hospitals may charge different payers different prices (including charges after a negotiated discount) for the same treatments and services, as some payers are more price-sensitive.
- The higher price charged to some payers (including self-payers) should average the relationship of cost to treatment or service for each patient served.
- The higher amount paid by certain payers might be intended not only to address below-cost reimbursements, but also the volume of payers and the desired total margin, especially of a for-profit hospital or healthcare organization.
When fixed costs rise (i.e. administrative expenses) the willingness of medical facilities to cost cut of possible price shifting may increase. When a group of payers become less price-sensitive, hospitals may charge payers a higher price, and so compensate for their losses. But that commonly does not happen by state insured patients. Their charges paid by a public insurer remain the same, because they are formed by law and bargained when a contract between facility and insurer is made. That further leads to weakening of market power of hospitals and healthcare organisations.
Cost cutting[]
Mendoza in his study[7] highlights that some studies suggest that hospital cost-cutting, if done efficiently, could absorb reimbursement shortfalls from either public or private payers. That means, if hospital management decides to cut costs, they can set an equilibrium. But they also have to exclude some services they have provided. However, there is no guarantee that it will be sustainable. Possible negative effect If policy makers fail to create proper borders could be a situation, which leads to unfair cost-shifting.
The Problem comes from the US government programs such as Medicare and Medicaid, where prices are set low by law and so are not always able to cover all expenses. Another fact[7] influencing a level of reimbursements are negotiations between healthcare providers and insurers. Insurance providers negotiate favourable prices which also have an influence on their own profit. Therefore, they prefer to set as low charges as possible.
Effect of Medicare and Medicaid on medical facilities[]
The main influence on American healthcare system in the USA has the Medicare for All Act written in 2003. It was transformed in 2019 so it was more efficient.[8]
Medicare and Medicaid are mostly preferred in rural areas, where there is also highest concentration of not-insured patients. Therefore, medical facilities have a much higher percentage of Medicare and Medicaid users and form a significant part of their income.[8]
Because there is a low presence of private insured patience, rural hospitals become dependent on these programs.
A change of law in 2019 promised to change the percentage difference between private payers and the state-insured. That means that revenues of rural hospitals would increase. But on the other hand, there could be caused a loss in revenues of urban hospitals, which budgets could therefore decrease.
Another big change[8] was that billing would be united into one single-payer healthcare system which was supposed to decrease administrative costs approximately by 50%.
Benefits and Losses of Cost-shifting[]
Cost-shifting is perceived as the most beneficial[7][8] for users of Medicare and Medicaid and for people who are not insured at all. It is likely that for users of Medicare and Medicaid could be in total paid lesser money in comparison with those, who pay classical insurance or are willing to pay on the spot. So, there could be caused a loss in a margin.
From former paragraph follows that patients, who are insured or pay on the spot, pay for their own treatment. But because there is already a loss, these patients have to pay also for the others. So, it is not beneficial for them.
Economics of Cost shifting[]
The cost shifting is the possibility to set different prices for different groups of customers. There are two important definitions: static cost shifting (price discrimination), that is the ability to charge different prices to different customers. The other one is the dynamic cost shifting, which means charging the maximal amount of money that the customer is able to pay (not necessarily the highest possible value, but the value that people are still willing to pay for the service).
For example, the hospitals may have two groups of patients. There are those who are covered by the government. From this group the hospital get fixed costs from the government. On the other hand, the second group of patients are those, who pay for their treatments. Those patients can buy more hospital care at a lower price.
The hospital that wants to earn as much profit as it can, has to decide whether it will accept patients covered by the government (lower income for hospital), and how much it should charge to the patients that pay for their treatments. This is another case of cost shifting. Both groups pay for the same service (hospital), but each has to pay different sum.
But in a competitive market there is rarely any price discrimination, nor cost shifting, because as soon as the hospital would have raised a price to one of those two groups of patients, they would seek care in some other hospital, therefore the hospital would only lose money.
References[]
- ^ Murphy, Dr. Brian: McCague Borlack LLP, "Cost Shifting in Health Care: A Pilot Study Explores the Relationships Between Cost Shifting, Repetitive Strain Injury, the Workplace Safety and Insurance Board of Ontario, and Publicly Funded Health Care" York University, 2003
- ^ "Preferred Medical Claim Solutions - Healthcare, Medical Claim Settlement Terms". Pmcsonline.com. Retrieved September 16, 2009.
- ^ "Behavioral Health Glossary". Pmhm.com. Archived from the original on January 5, 2009. Retrieved September 16, 2009.
- ^ Wangsness, Lisa (June 21, 2009). "Healthcare debate shifting to public vs. private - The Boston Globe". Boston.com. Retrieved September 16, 2009.
- ^ Health Affairs Chapin White, May 2013.
- ^ Morrisey, Michael A. (1994). Cost Shifting in Health Care Separating Evidence from Rhetoric (PDF). Washington D.C.: The AEI Press.
- ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l Roger Lee Mendoza, Ph D. (2020-07-07). "Cost-Shifting and Cost-Cutting as Joint and Mutually Reinforcing Strategies in the Financial Management of Hospitals and Similar Healthcare Organizations". Journal of Health Care Finance.
- ^ a b c d e Fitzpatrick, Meagan C.; Galvani, Alison P. (2020-10-31). "The effect of Medicare for All on rural hospitals – Authors' reply". The Lancet. 396 (10260): 1392–1393. doi:10.1016/S0140-6736(20)32216-9. ISSN 0140-6736. PMID 33129384.
- ^ "The Cost Shift Myth". www.coloradohealthinstitute.org. Retrieved 2021-04-18.
See also[]
- Health economics
- Economics and finance stubs