Lausanne School
The Lausanne School of economics, sometimes referred to as the Mathematical School, refers to the neoclassical economics school of thought surrounding Léon Walras and Vilfredo Pareto. It is named after the University of Lausanne, at which both Walras and Pareto held professorships. Polish economist Leon Winiarski is also said to have been a member of the Lausanne School.[1]
Background[]
The term Lausanne School was first coined by the mathematician Hermann Laurent in his article Petit traite d'economie politique mathematique (Small Treatise on Mathematical Political Economy).[2] The central feature of the Lausanne School was its development of general equilibrium theory. Laurent's article presented a simplified version of this theory.[2]
Lausanne School is also associated with the Italian School and the Paretian School, which were based on the works of Pareto.[3] Italian economic historians have adopted Luigi Einaudi's description that the age of the Lausanne School in Italy should be called "Italian school".[3] The school is distinguished from the work of Alfred Marshall by the way it maintains the necessity of considering the interaction of all parts of the economy simultaneously so that the behavior that occurs within any part of it can be understood.[4] Marshall, on the other hand, preferred to solve economic problems using mathematics as the instrument, with the theorist drawing out conclusions instead of coming up with solutions through the process of verbal reasoning.[4]
The Lausanne School attempted to answer the question of whether the welfare of an economy can be measured.[5] Its theorists such as Walras proposed that it can be done through a notion of justice in exchange called "commutative justice", which required all traders to face the same price, which did not change, for a given product. This free competition is said to produce "maximum welfare", allowing for an effective evaluation of questions of welfare.[6] Hans Mayer argued against Lausanne School, citing that its assumptions are unrealistic and that the utility of a good cannot be measured, infinitely divided, nor indefinitely substituted.[7]
Members of the Lausanne School include Basile Samsonoff, Marie Kolabinska, and Pierre Boven, who were all students of Pareto.[8]
References[]
- ^ Garrouste, Pierre and Ioannides, Stavros. (2001). Evolution and Path Dependence in Economic Ideas (Lausanne school: Winiarski a member, pg. 184). Edward Elgar Publishing.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Faccarello, Gilbert; Kurz, Heinz D. (2016). Handbook on the History of Economic Analysis Volume II: Schools of Thought in Economics. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. p. 281. ISBN 9781849801119.
- ^ Jump up to: a b McLure, Michael (2007). The Paretian School and Italian Fiscal Sociology. Hampshire, UK: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 19. ISBN 9781349547982.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Cate, Thomas (2013). An Encyclopedia of Keynesian Economics, Second edition. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. p. 387. ISBN 9781849801720.
- ^ Suntum, Ulrich van (2005). The Invisible Hand: Economic Thought Yesterday and Today. Berlin: Springer Science & Business Media. p. 30. ISBN 3-540-20497-0.
- ^ Backhouse, Roger E. (2002). The Penguin History of Economics. London: Penguin UK. ISBN 978-0-14-193743-4.
- ^ Schulak, Eugen-Maria; Unterköfler, Herbert (2011). The Austrian School of Economics: A History of Its Ideas, Ambassadors, and Institutions. Auburn, Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute. p. 110. ISBN 978-1-61016-498-6.
- ^ Allisson, François; Baranzini, Roberto (2014). Economics and Other Branches – In the Shade of the Oak Tree: Essays in Honour of Pascal Bridel. Oxon: Routledge. p. 113. ISBN 978-1-84893-533-4.
Further reading[]
- Gherity, James A. (1965). Economic Thought: a Historical Anthology (article: The Lausanne School, pg. 352-). Ransom House.
External links[]
- Schools of economic thought
- Economic history stubs