Third Vote

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

The Third Vote (German: Drittstimme) is an election method proposed within the mathematical theory of democracy by Andranik Tangian. It is aimed at emphasizing issues of policy over personality[1] The Third Vote has to-date only been used experimentally in student elections.

Description[]

The aim of the Third Vote method is to draw the voters' attention from personalities of politicians to policy issues, that is, from the question "Who should be elected?" to "What do we choose?". Therefore, the electors do not cast votes by candidate name, but give Yes/No-answers to several policy questions as raised in the candidates' manifestos. The same procedure is inherent in voting advice applications (VAA) but the results are evaluated in a different way. In contrast to VAAs, answering the questionnaire implies no voting recommendation for the individual user. Instead, the answers of all voters are processed, and the political profile of the entire electorate is built with the balance of public opinion of pros/cons percentages for each issue. The election winner is the candidate whose policy profile (constituted by his/her Yes/No-answers to the same questions) best matches with that of the electorate.

If the candidates are political parties competing for parliament seats, the proximity of the party profiles to the electorate profile is indexed, and the parliament seats are allocated proportionally to the party indices. When considering decision options instead of candidates (whan a commission has to agree on a certain business plan, technical proposal, etc.), the questions focus on their specific characteristics.

Since the electorate is considered a single body with a single policy profile, no multiple-voter paradox like that of Borda, Condorcet or Arrow can arise.

History[]

The Third Vote method was developed in the 2010s at the Hans Böckler Foundation and the Karlsruhe Institute of Technology as part of the mathematical theory of democracy[2][3] in order to improve policy representation and surmount the voters' irrationality. Although this voting method is completely self-sufficient, it was first tested as a complement to the two-vote system. The name "Third Vote" emphasizes the complementarity to the two-vote system of mixed-member proportional representation, which is used in Germany, New Zealand, Bolivia, Lesotho, Thailand, South Africa, South Korea, United Kingdom (Scotland, Wales, and the London assembly) and Ethiopia.

The Third Vote was implemented during the annual student parliament elections (StuPa elections) 2016–2019 at the Karlsruhe Institute of Technology.[4][5][6][7] The experiments were monitored on the Third Vote website[8] and the results were discussed in the German media[9][10][11][12][13] as well as at the 2016 and 2019 World Forums for Democracy.[14][15]

Example[]

Table 1 shows five dichotomous questions (assuming Yes/No answers) and the answers from three parties - Conservatives, Socialists and Greens - and from three equal groups of voters - A, B and C. (Questions 1 to 5 are the Questions 1, 2, 7, 28 and 32 from the 2017 German VAA Wahl-O-Mat, and the answers to these questions are that of the German conservative party CDU/CSU, the Social Democrats SPD and the greens GRÜNE.[16]

Table 1: Policy profiles of three parties and three voter groups, the party representativeness indices, and allocation of parliament seats
Questions Parties Voter group Balance of public opinion
Conservatives Socialists Greens A B C Yes No
1. Counter-terrorism domestic deployment of the army Yes No No No Yes No 1/3 2/3
2. Higher taxes for diesel fuel No No Yes No Yes Yes 2/3 1/3
3. Extending video surveillance Yes Yes No Yes No No 1/3 2/3
4. Statutory health insurance for all No Yes Yes Yes No Yes 2/3 1/3
5. Allow cannabis sales No No Yes No No No 0 3/3
Popularity (average size of the group represented), in% 47 60 53
Parliament faction size, in % 29 38 33

Table 1 contains the party representation index "Popularity", which is the average size of the group represented. For example, the Conservatives answer Questions 1 to 4 as 1/3 of all voters and Question 5 as all voters (3/3). That leads to

The popularity of the Socialists and Greens is calculated in the same way, giving 60% and 53%, respectively. The election winners are therefore the Socialists.

The parliamentary seats are allocated in proportion to the parties’ indices of Popularity:

The Third Vote is also applicable in the context of collective multiple-criteria decision making.[17]

Implementation[]

Formulation of the questions. The questions are proposed by the candidates themselves - as part of the election campaign. After that, each candidate answers all questions, including the questions from other candidates. Thereby, complete policy profiles of all candidates are defined.

Final selection of questions. The final selection of a reasonable number of questions for the ballot, which best emphasize the contrast between the candidates, is done either by a special commission, as in the case of VAAs, or by a computer program that analyzes the parties' answers.

Unequal importance of questions. The voters can optionally assign question weights (e.g. from 0 - unimportant to 5 - very important). The sum of the voter weights for each question is then used to determine the "average" public opinion about the relative importance of each issue, which is then used in calculations.

Taking into account the candidates’ credibility. To account for voter confidence, the Third Vote is combined with traditional voting by candidate name. The final rating of the candidates is then based on the average of the candidate's Popularity index and the percentage of votes the candidate received.

Ballot. An exemplary ballot form, which is virtually filled in by a voter from Group A, is shown in Table 2.

Table 2: Ballot form virtually completed by a voter from Group A
Question Yes No Weight (optional)
1. Counter-terrorism domestic deployment of the army X 1
2. Higher taxes for diesel fuel X 1
3. Extending video surveillance X 1
4. Statutory health insurance for all X 1
5. Allow cannabis sales X 1
Vote for a party (optional)
Conservatives
Socialists X
Greens

The Third Vote versus plurality vote, Borda count and Condorcet count[]

In the above example, the Third Vote finds a single winner, whereas no single winner is found by the plurality vote (the electors cast votes for the favorite candidate) and the Condorcet and Borda counts, which use the electors' preference orders shown in Table 3. In parentheses, the VAA-ratings are indicated, that is, the number of coincidences in the voter and party profiles. For example, Voter Group 1 coincides with the Socialists in 5 issues, with the Conservatives in 3 issues and the Greens in 2 issues. Therefore, Group 1's preference ordering is Socialists > Conservatives > Greens.

Table 3: Preference orderings of the voters (with VAA-assisted ratings of the parties)
Rank Preference orderings of Voter Groups
A B C
1 Socialists (5) Conservatives (3) Greens (4)
2 Conservatives (3) Greens (2) Socialists (3)
3 Greens (2) Socialists (1) Conservatives (1)

Table 4 shows that neither plurality vote nor the Borda count (sum of ranks) nor Condorcet count (pairwise vote) results in a single winner.

Table 4: Plurality vote, Borda scores and pairwise vote, resulting in a Condorcet cycle
Conservatives Socialists Greens
Plurality votes 1 1 1
Borda score (sum of ranks) 2+1+3=6 1+3+2=6 3+2+1=6
Pairwise vote Vote ratios
Conservatives 1:2 2:1
Socialists 2:1 1:2
Greens 1:2 2:1

Indeed, each voter group has its own favorite candidate, the sums of ranks (Borda count) are the same for all three candidates, and the pairwise vote (Condorcet count) leads to a Condorcet cycle without the weakest link to be cut:

References[]

  1. ^ Budge, Ian; McDonald, Michael D (2007). "Election and party system effects on policy representation: Bringing time into a comparative perspective". Electoral Studies. 26 (1): 168–179. doi:10.1016/j.electstud.2006.02.001.
  2. ^ Tangian, Andranik (2014). Mathematical theory of democracy. Studies in Choice and Welfare. Berlin-Heidelberg: Springer. doi:10.1007/978-3-642-38724-1. ISBN 978-3-642-38723-4.
  3. ^ Tangian, Andranik (2020). Analytical theory of democracy. Vols. 1 and 2. Studies in Choice and Welfare. Cham, Switzerland: Springer. doi:10.1007/978-3-030-39691-6. ISBN 978-3-030-39690-9.
  4. ^ "Drittstimmenaktion: Eine neue Idee zur Umsetzung direkter Demokratie (Third vote action: A new idea for implementing direct democracy)". AStA Ventil, 1 July 2016. Karlsruhe: Karlsruhe Institute of Technology, AStA. 134: 6. Retrieved 30 December 2019.
  5. ^ "The Third Vote: Eine neue Idee zur Umsetzung direkter Demokratie (The Third Vote: A new idea for implementing direct democracy)" (PDF). Ventil StuPa-Wahl, 23 June 2017. Karlsruhe: Karlsruhe Institute of Technology, AStA. 136. Retrieved 30 December 2019.
  6. ^ "The Third Vote: Improving our Democracy" (PDF). Wahlventil 15 June 2018 – Ventil (in German). Karlsruhe: Karlsruhe Institute of Technology, AStA. 141: 7–8. Retrieved 15 February 2021.
  7. ^ "The Third Vote: Eine neue Idee zur Umsetzung direkter Demokratie (The Third Vote: A new idea to implement direct democracy)" (PDF). Wahlventil 28 June 2019 (in German). Karlsruhe: Karlsruhe Institute of Technology, AStA. 143: 12–13. Retrieved 15 February 2021.
  8. ^ Amrhein, Marius; Diemer, Antonia; Eßwein, Bastian; Waldeck, Maximilian; Schäfer, Sebastian. "The Third Vote (web page)". Karlsruhe: Karlsruhe Institute of Technology, Institute ECON. Retrieved 15 December 2020.
  9. ^ Klein, Manuel T. (21 March 2011). "Von Wahlen, Wählern und Gewählten (Of elections, voters and elected)" (PDF). Die Rheinpfalz (in German). 67. Retrieved 19 February 2021.
  10. ^ Kinkel, Ekart (6 May 2014). "Plädoyer für die Drittstimme: KIT-Forscher für sanfte Reform des Wahlrechts (Plea for the third vote: KIT researcher for soft reform of the electoral law)" (PDF). Badische Neueste Nachrichten (in German). 103: 15. Retrieved 19 February 2021.
  11. ^ Schmidt, Nicola (7 October 2016). "Denn sie wissen nicht, was sie wählen (Then they do not know what they elect)". Autopilot An! Perspective-Daily (in German). Retrieved 19 February 2021.
  12. ^ Dittrich, Tobias; Tangian, Andranik (2017). "Politische Technologien gegen Populismus (Political technologies against populism)" (PDF). Karlsruhe Transfer (KT) (in German). 52: 8–11. Retrieved 20 February 2021.
  13. ^ Kinkel, Ekart (2017). "Die Drittstimme: Volkswirtschaftsprofessor Andranik S. Tangian hat am KIT ein alternatives Wahlverfahren zur Repräsentanz des Bürgerwillens entwickelt (The Third Vote: Economics professor Andranik S. Tangian has developed an alternative election method to represent citizens' wishes)" (PDF). LooKIT (in German and English) (2): 74–76. Retrieved 19 February 2021.
  14. ^ "Turning a political education instrument (voting advice application) in a new election method", World Forum for Democracy 2016, Lab 7: Reloading Elections, Strasbourg: Council of Europe, 7–9 November 2016, retrieved 15 December 2020
  15. ^ "Well Informed Vote", World Forum for Democracy 2019, Lab 5: Voting under the Influence, Strasbourg: Council of Europe, 6–8 November 2019, retrieved 15 December 2020
  16. ^ Bundeszentrale für politische Bildung. "Wahl-O-Mat". Berlin. Retrieved 15 December 2020.
  17. ^ Tangian, Andranik (2021). "MCDM application of the Third Vote" (PDF). Group Decision and Negotiation. 30 (4): 775–787. doi:10.1007/s10726-021-09733-2.
Retrieved from ""