Sum (administrative division)

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Sum, sumu, sumon, and somon (Plural: sumd) are the lowest level of administrative division used in China, Mongolia, and Russia. The word sumu is a direct translation of a Manchu word niru, meaning ‘arrow’ [1] Countries such as China and Mongolia, have employed the sumu administrative processes in order to fulfil their nations economic, social and political goals. This system was acted in the 1980s after the Chinese Communist Party gained power in conjunction with their growing internal and external problems. The decentralisation of government included restructuring of organisational methods, reduction of roles in rural government and creation of sumu’s.[2]

China[]

In Inner Mongolia, a sumu (Mongolian: ᠰᠤᠮᠤ, сум, transliteration: sumu; Chinese: 苏木, pinyin: sūmù) is a township-level political/administrative division. The sumu division is equivalent to a township but is unique to Inner Mongolia. It is therefore larger than a gaqa (Mongolian: ᠭᠠᠴᠠᠭᠠ гацаа) and smaller than a banner (the Inner Mongolia equivalent of the county-level division). Examples include Shiwei, Inner Mongolia and Honggor Sumu, Siziwang Banner.

Sumu whose population is predominated by ethnic minorities are designated ethnic sumu – parallel with the ethnic township in the rest of China. As of 2010, there is only one ethnic sumu in China, the Evenk Ethnic Sumu.

Mongolia[]

A sum (Mongolian: сум, ᠰᠤᠮᠤ) is the second level administrative division below the Aimags (provinces), roughly comparable to a County in the United States. There are 331 sums in Mongolia. Each sum is again divided into .[3]

Russia[]

In Russia, a sumon is an administrative division of the Tuva Republic, and somon is that of the Buryat Republic. Both are describing the Russian term "selsoviet".

History[]

The past century saw immense change in the local administrative processes within China, invoked by political movement, civil wars and the changing role of rural regions. This eventually turned in the sumu system in 1983.[4]

1961-1982[]

In the period of 1961-1983, China introduced the commune-brigade system to locally administrate “socio-economic functions” under the rule of Mao Zedong.[5]

The commune is the lowest rank of authority in the Chinese government underneath the “central government, provincial (autonomous region) government and county government.” [6] The commune authority had the responsibility of specific key functions including supplementing reinforcement to the army regime, fluent connections between party members, administration of economic goals and ensuring correct was carried out in response to crime. It helped orchestrate and maintain three integral organisations that overlooked women’s role in society, developing the youth generation and fulfilling needs of herdsman.[7]

The brigade authority supplemented the commune role, through the organisations of meetings that enacted the plans and policies defined by the commune. It oversaw grassland protection schemes, preservation of livestock, the family planning programme, taxation processes and financially supported herdsman. Resources such as tractors, storage houses and general equipment required to carry out economic functions were organised by the unit. The brigade provided resources needed to carry out infrastructure projects directed by upper authorities.[8]

1983[]

The 1980s was the period of decentralisation and mass reformation within the domestic economic, trading systems and finance. This included greater integration of rural government in economic decisions.[9] 1983 was China’s first administrative reform, aimed to restructure the government and establish a “retirement and tenure system.” This aimed to reduce individuals in government positions for long periods of time.[10] It meant the dissolvement of commune-brigade system, reforming into the sumu-gaca system. This system still retains the political and administrative functions, however, not involved in the agricultural organisation.[11]

The collective livestock was redistricted to households within the gaca (previously called the brigade) based on the capacity of the households, roughly equating to over 50 per person.[12] This determined the territory distributed according to the size and needs of animals. Native herdsmen were given favoured distribution due to their experience and knowledge.[13]

The reform meant some government roles were united, reducing the number of overall positions within the sumu. This reduced total number of agencies from 60 to 50 in provinces, 40 to 30 in the autonomous regions and 40 to 25 in counties. In regional provinces within China and Mongolia, “staffing decreased from over 180,000 to about 120,000” [14] This reformation involved a significant time lag in implementation due to the large scope of townships and their cultural differences. The reform was due to the economic needs of China, and increased demand for economic improvement.[15] The restructure of government-based institutions was to redistribute sumu’s role in responding to economic shocks and high-level authority requests.[16]

Role of Members[]

The ruling authority in the sumu was the communist party committee (CPC), in charge of overseeing economic functions and structuring the administration of the party members. This would consist of approximately seven to nine members.[17] CPC leadership played a key role on the administrative level, to supervise smaller scale economic activity and to voice local concerns to higher-level agencies.[18]

Chinese Communist Party Committee

The secretary was the leading position, having the defining voice in party decisions. The chief of the commune management committee provided strict guidelines and control over general administration and ensured the economic goals were being supported by action.[19] The third member overruled the disciplinary order and action over the state including the punishment of crime and policing of regional law.[20] The chief of people’s militia overlooked the supplementary military team consisting of approximately 150 members. This male team were occasionally needed in situations where the national level of military required support.[21] The remaining members aided in the management and organisation of major clubs such as the Youth League and Women’s League.[22]

Impact on Population[]

Migration[]

Migration saw an increase under the previous commune-brigade system, due to the introduction of collective hard labour tasks requiring migrants with agricultural background. The shift to the sumu system meant the removal of work assignments by higher authorities. This saw a spike of migrants moving back out of sumu’s in conquest for stable employment opportunities.[23] The Chinese State Statistical Bureau released a national survey in 1987 showing that between the years 1982 and 1987 there was a net rural-urban migration of 13 million, in comparison to the 35 million in the period of 1978 and 1982.[24] The old system provided work points and residential registration, in exchange for the completion of tasks rejected by the native’s herdsman. These tasks included gardening, supply of food chain, use of gardening equipment, construction work and other one-off tasks enforced by the government.[25]

Impact on Agriculture[]

Distribution of Land[]

Despite the productivity gains land distribution was still skewed under the idea that land was owned by every member of the sumu, neglecting the arduous nature of agricultural maintenance. The entirety of the population had claim on land property and the distribution was primarily based of size of household members and villager stater commonly disregarded accumulation of skill and experience.[26] This eligibility system increased the worry in farmers about losing land and investment. This partially stagnated growth and reduced motivation to develop agricultural infrastructure.[27] The irrigation system remained unchanged in the 1980s, due to the technical difficulty and risk induced nature of developing it.[28]

Grassland Mongolia 1983

The distribution of land caused disputes amongst livestock keepers, as the natural requirement for certain pasturage was not taken into account in the division of land.[29] Farmland in these areas differed in terms of soil types, access to irrigation resources and the types of plants they can foster.[30] The reformation left unconsidered the “indivisibility of pasture necessary for seasonal pasturage” and how different locations change according to the soil type and exposure to extreme conditions.[31] Cultivated was left to waste seasonally and commonly fragmented as boundaries were formed to separate households and create divisions.[32]

A survey conducted by the Chinese Ministry of Agriculture of 7983 sample villages within the Chinese provinces showed that in 1986, “average cultivated area per household 0.466 ha (7 mu),3 fragmented into 5.85 plots, each plot on average 0.08 ha” [33] This method of division has remained in modern society limiting these areas in using more advanced methods of production that capitalise on technical infrastructures.[34] The constant redistribution of land was embedded with additional costs and time, reducing the efficiency of the implementation process.[35]

Before the introduction of sumus, pasture of herdsman would shift from mountains to lowlands, in response to seasonal change. The territorial-administrative division meant that within Mongolia, 60 sumus were strictly in high mountain regions and 40 were in forage dense areas. The homogenisation initially restricted gross pasture produced by each sumu and overall health of livestock.[36]

The land currently owned by the Ogiinuur Sum, in Mongolia, was previously used for strictly summer and fall pasture due to the seasons. In 1983, the redistribution of land meant the sum allocated to the land had no appropriate pasture for the remaining two seasons. This caused high fatality rates in livestock. In 1983, this Ogiinuur Sum faced the highest percentage of deaths in total livestock within Mongolia.[37]

Exports[]

The administrative reform coincided with the Central Committee of the Communist Party of China (CPC) deciding to increase prices of agricultural products to seek greater revenue and economic profit.[38] The previous commune system had export restrains with the ways in which land was distributed restricting its economic efficiency. Previously, government administration would purchase agricultural goods below market value, dampening farmers desirability to work efficiently [39] The reformation of the 1980s allowed China to face growth after 30 years of economic stagnation. The relaxion of agricultural laws provided incentive for farmers to perform at a higher level due to increase freedom and ability to make more informed decisions. This revival of the administration system saw a dramatic increase in export performance on the long-term average.[40]

China’s gross export of grain equated to 283 million tonnes with output rate of 2600 kh/ha of raw grain in 1977

Grain harvesting in Xizhou county

[41] The production of grain increased to 407 million tonnes in 1984. This made it the largest contributor to exports.[42] This increase in productivity solved the ongoing issue of being unable to fulfil both state demand and feeding rural households.[43] Between 1978 and 1984 the three major outputs of China’s commodities markets including “grain, cotton and oil-bearing crops increased at annual rates of 4.8 percent, 7.7 percent and 13.8 percent”, in comparison to 1952 to 1978 before which faced average rates of increase of “2.4 percent, 1.0 percent and 0.8 percent” [44]

The change in the commune system also came with the introduction of the household responsibility system (HRS) that eased traditional rules surrounding agricultural production. This allowed experimentation of production modes and increased resource availability. Selling of goods was now allowed to go straight to the market instead of through government officials. The sumu administration processes further diversified the agricultural goods to be made, with a growth of cotton and fruits, thus bringing more opportunities for economic growth.[45]

From 1978 to 1984 the agricultural sectors input to GDP grew annually by 6.8% which elevated GDP growth by 1.5 percent, allowing for immense infrastructure development within China at this time. This heavily benefits farmers who saw an increase in income of 15.7 percent from 1978 to 1984.[46] In 1985, this market did experience drop the benefits of the household responsibility system stagnated. This was not solely due to land institutional reform but compliment with real grain price shifts and increased external competition. In 1985, this market did experience drop the benefits of the household responsibility system stagnated. This was not solely due to land institutional reform but compliment with real grain price shifts and increased external competition.[47]

Non-Agricultural Business[]

The sumu administration shift saw an increase in productivity which led to decline in the need for rural workers. However, that’s predominant income was derived from non-agricultural activities had immense growth. The shift to sum administration relaxed restrictions surrounding access to machinery and processing materials, facilitating for growth in production fields.[48] These towns become major contributors to economic growth. Their availability to resource allows them to quickly respond to changing demand in the urban areas. Employment in these towns increased from 23 million in 1977 to 52 million in 1984. This heavily benefits farmers who saw an increase in income of 15.7 percent from 1978 to 1984.[49]

See also[]

References[]

  1. ^ Cosmo, N. D. (1998). Qing Colonial Administration in Inner Asia . The International Review , 20(2), 287-309.
  2. ^ Baskaran, S., & Ihjas, M. (2019). The Development of Public Administration in the People’s Republic of China: An Analysis of Administrative Reform. Civil Service Management and Administrative Systems in South Asia , 305-323.
  3. ^ Ole Bruun Precious Steppe: Mongolian Nomadic Pastoralists in Pursuit of the Market. 2006- Page 68 "The historical administrative units of aimag, sum, and bag (Khotont constitutes one of nineteen sums in Arkangai aimag) still form the bases of "
  4. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  5. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  6. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  7. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  8. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  9. ^ Baskaran, S., & Ihjas, M. (2019). The Development of Public Administration in the People’s Republic of China: An Analysis of Administrative Reform. Civil Service Management and Administrative Systems in South Asia , 305-323.
  10. ^ Baskaran, S., & Ihjas, M. (2019). The Development of Public Administration in the People’s Republic of China: An Analysis of Administrative Reform. Civil Service Management and Administrative Systems in South Asia , 305-323.
  11. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  12. ^ Tang, R., & Michael, G. C. (2015). Degradation and re-emergence of the commons: The impacts of government policies on traditional resource management institutions in China. Environmental Science & Policy, 52, 89-98.
  13. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  14. ^ Yang, D. (2003). A Study of Administrative Reform in China. M.A. dissertation, Central China Normal University, Wuhan.
  15. ^ Straussman, J. D., & Mengzhong, Z. (2001). Chinese Administrative Reform in International Perspective. The International Journal of Public Sector Management, 14(5), 411–422.
  16. ^ Baskaran, S., & Ihjas, M. (2019). The Development of Public Administration in the People’s Republic of China: An Analysis of Administrative Reform. Civil Service Management and Administrative Systems in South Asia , 305-323.
  17. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  18. ^ Aufrecht, S. E., & Bun, L. S. (1995). Reform with Chinese Characteristics: The Context of Chinese Civil Service Reform. Public Administration Review, 55(2), 175–182.
  19. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  20. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  21. ^ Cosmo, N. D. (1998). Qing Colonial Administration in Inner Asia . The International Review , 20(2), 287-309.
  22. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  23. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  24. ^ Chan, K. W. (1994). Urbanization and Rural-Urban Migration in China since 1982: A New Baseline. Modern China, 20(3), 243-281.
  25. ^ Rong, M. (2003). Changes in Local Administration and their Impact on Community Life in the Grasslands of Inner Mongolia, China. China Report , 39(4), 459-475.
  26. ^ Chen, F., & David, J. (n.d.). Land reform in rural China since the mid-1980s. Retrieved from Fao.org: http://www.fao.org/3/x1372t/x1372t10.htm
  27. ^ Chen, F., & David, J. (n.d.). Land reform in rural China since the mid-1980s. Retrieved from Fao.org: http://www.fao.org/3/x1372t/x1372t10.htm
  28. ^ Ministry of Agriculture of China. (1993). Survey on agrarian operation under household responsibility system in China. Problems of Agricultural Economy, 11, 45-52.
  29. ^ Bold, B.-O. (1997). The coordination of territorial-administrative divisions with pastoral areas: an important prerequisite for the effective use of pasture land. Mongolian Studies , 20, 1-22.
  30. ^ Chen, F., & David, J. (n.d.). Land reform in rural China since the mid-1980s. Retrieved from Fao.org: http://www.fao.org/3/x1372t/x1372t10.htm
  31. ^ Bold, B.-O. (1997). The coordination of territorial-administrative divisions with pastoral areas: an important prerequisite for the effective use of pasture land. Mongolian Studies , 20, 1-22.
  32. ^ Chen, F., & David, J. (n.d.). Land reform in rural China since the mid-1980s. Retrieved from Fao.org: http://www.fao.org/3/x1372t/x1372t10.htm
  33. ^ Ministry of Agriculture of China. (1993). Survey on agrarian operation under household responsibility system in China. Problems of Agricultural Economy, 11, 45-52.
  34. ^ Chen, F., & David, J. (n.d.). in rural China since the mid-1980s. Retrieved from Fao.org: http://www.fao.org/3/x1372t/x1372t10.htm
  35. ^ Ministry of Agriculture of China. (1993). Survey on agrarian operation under household responsibility system in China. Problems of Agricultural Economy, 11, 45-52.
  36. ^ Baskaran, S., & Ihjas, M. (2019). The Development of Public Administration in the People’s Republic of China: An Analysis of Administrative Reform. Civil Service Management and Administrative Systems in South Asia , 305-323.
  37. ^ Bold, B.-O. (1997). The coordination of territorial-administrative divisions with pastoral areas: an important prerequisite for the effective use of pasture land. Mongolian Studies , 20, 1-22.
  38. ^ Wang, X. (2018 ). 10. China’s macroeconomics in the 40 years of reform . In R. Garnaut, L. Song, & C. Fang, China’s 40 Years of Reform and Development: 1978–2018 . ANU Press.
  39. ^ Wang, X. (2018 ). 10. China’s macroeconomics in the 40 years of reform . In R. Garnaut, L. Song, & C. Fang, China’s 40 Years of Reform and Development: 1978–2018 . ANU Press.
  40. ^ Chen, F., & David, J. (n.d.). Land reform in rural China since the mid-1980s. Retrieved from Fao.org: http://www.fao.org/3/x1372t/x1372t10.htm
  41. ^ Wang, X. (2018 ). 10. China’s macroeconomics in the 40 years of reform . In R. Garnaut, L. Song, & C. Fang, China’s 40 Years of Reform and Development: 1978–2018 . ANU Press.
  42. ^ Chen, F., & David, J. (n.d.). Land reform in rural China since the mid-1980s. Retrieved from Fao.org: http://www.fao.org/3/x1372t/x1372t10.htm
  43. ^ Wang, X. (2018 ). 10. China’s macroeconomics in the 40 years of reform . In R. Garnaut, L. Song, & C. Fang, China’s 40 Years of Reform and Development: 1978–2018 . ANU Press.
  44. ^ State Statistical Bureau, People's Republic of China. (1985). China Statistical Yearbook. Beijing: China Statistical Publishing House.
  45. ^ Wang, X. (2018 ). 10. China’s macroeconomics in the 40 years of reform . In R. Garnaut, L. Song, & C. Fang, China’s 40 Years of Reform and Development: 1978–2018 . ANU Press.
  46. ^ Wang, X. (2018 ). 10. China’s macroeconomics in the 40 years of reform . In R. Garnaut, L. Song, & C. Fang, China’s 40 Years of Reform and Development: 1978–2018 . ANU Press.
  47. ^ Chen, F., & David, J. (n.d.). Land reform in rural China since the mid-1980s. Retrieved from Fao.org: http://www.fao.org/3/x1372t/x1372t10.htm
  48. ^ Wang, X. (2018 ). 10. China’s macroeconomics in the 40 years of reform . In R. Garnaut, L. Song, & C. Fang, China’s 40 Years of Reform and Development: 1978–2018 . ANU Press.
  49. ^ Wang, X. (2018 ). 10. China’s macroeconomics in the 40 years of reform . In R. Garnaut, L. Song, & C. Fang, China’s 40 Years of Reform and Development: 1978–2018 . ANU Press.


Retrieved from ""