Carbon emission trading

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Carbon emission trade - allowance prices from 2008


Emission trading schemes (ETS) for carbon dioxide (CO
2
) and other greenhouse gases (GHGs) are an approach to limit climate change by creating a market with limited allowances for emissions. Additional costs on GHG emissions can lower competitiveness of fossil fuels and accelerate investments into low carbon sources of energy such as wind power and photovoltaics. Fossil fuels are the main driver for climate change. They account for 89% of all CO
2
emissions and 68% of all GHG emissions.[1]

Under emission trading, a country or a polluter having more emissions is able to purchase the right to emit more. The country or entity having fewer emissions sells the right to emit carbon to other countries or entities. As a result, the most cost-effective carbon reduction methods would be exploited first. ETS and carbon taxes are a common method for countries to meet their pledges under the Paris Agreement.

Carbon ETS are in operation in China, the European Union and other countries.[2] However, they are usually not harmonized with any defined carbon budgets, which are required to maintain global warming below the critical thresholds of 1.5°C or "well below" 2°C. The existing schemes only cover a limited scope of emissions. The EU-ETS focusses on industry and large power generation, leaving the introduction of additional schemes for transport and private consumption to the member states. Though units are counted in tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent, other potent GHGs such as methane (CH
4
) or nitrous oxide (N
2
O
) from agriculture are usually not part these schemes yet. Apart from that, an oversupply leads to low prices of allowances with almost no effect on fossil fuel combustion.[3] In July 2021, emission trade allowances (ETAs) covered a wide price range from 6€/tCO
2
in China's new national carbon market[4] to 57€/tCO
2
in the EU-ETS.[5] The German Environment Agency estimates the environmental damage between €180 (206 $) and €640/tCO
2
(731 $).[6]

History[]

The international community began the long process towards building effective international and domestic measures to tackle GHG emissions (carbon dioxide, methane, nitrous oxide, hydroflurocarbons, perfluorocarbons, sulphur hexafluoride) in response to the increasing assertions that global warming is happening due to man-made emissions and the uncertainty over its likely consequences. That process began in Rio de Janeiro in 1992, when 160 countries agreed the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). The necessary detail was left to be settled by the UN Conference of Parties (COP).

In 1997, the Kyoto Protocol was the first major agreement to reduce greenhouse gases. 38 developed countries (Annex 1 countries) committed themselves to targets and timetables.[7]

The resulting inflexible limitations on GHG growth could entail substantial costs if countries have to solely rely on their own domestic measures.[8]

Economics[]

Emissions trading works by setting a quantitative limit on the emissions produced by emitters.

Costs and valuation[]

The economic problem with climate change is that the emitters of greenhouse gases (GHGs) do not face the full cost implications of their actions.[9] There are costs that emitters do face, e.g., the costs of the fuel being used, but there are other costs that are not necessarily included in the price of a good or service. These other costs are called external costs (Halsnæs et al.., 2007).[10] They are "external" because they are costs that the emitter does not carry. External costs may affect the welfare of others. In the case of climate change, GHG emissions affect the welfare of people now and in the future, as well as affecting the natural environment (Toth et al., 2005 ).[11] These external costs can be estimated[citation needed] and converted into a common (monetary) unit. The argument for doing this is that these external costs can then be added to the private costs that the emitter faces. In doing this, the emitter faces the full (social) costs of their actions (IMF, 2008, p. 9), and will therefore take these costs into account in their decisions and actions.

Ethics and fairness[]

The manner in which climate change is addressed involves ethical and other issues related to fairness. To actually calculate social cost requires value judgements about the value of future climate impacts (Smith et al.., 2001).[12] There is no consensus among economists over how to value the fairness (economists use the term equity to mean fairness) of a particular climate policy, e.g., how to share the burden of costs for mitigating future climate change (Toth et al., 2001).[13] Nor do economists have any professional expertise in making ethical decisions, e.g., over the value assigned to the welfare of future generations (Arrow et al.., 1996, p. 130).[14] Typically all the impacts of policy, both the costs and benefits, are added together (aggregation), with different impacts on different individuals assigned particular "weightings," i.e., relative levels of importance. These valuations are chosen by the economist doing the study. Valuations can be difficult since not all goods have a market price.

There are methods to infer prices for "non-market" goods and services. However, these valuations are still in development, e.g., valuations of human health impacts, or impacts on ecosystems (Smith et al.., 2001).[15] There is a growing realization that potentially positive benefits from climate change in particular regions, e.g., tourism, do not offset negative impacts in other regions, e.g., reduced food production (Smith et al.., 2001).[16] The main advantage of economic analysis in this area is that it allows a comprehensive and consistent treatment of climate change impacts.[citation needed] It also allows the benefits of climate change policy decisions to be compared against other possible environmental policies.[citation needed]

Taxes versus caps[]

A number of papers in the economics literature suggest that carbon taxes should be preferred to carbon trading (Carbon Trust, 2009).[17] Counter-arguments to this are usually based on the possible preference that politicians may have for emissions trading compared with taxes (Bashmakov et al.., 2001).[18] Emissions permits can be freely distributed to polluting industries, or can be auctioned to create a carbon market. Industries may successfully lobby to exempt themselves from a carbon tax. It is therefore argued that with emissions trading, polluters have an incentive to cut emissions, but if they are exempted from a carbon tax, they have no incentive to cut emissions (Smith, 2008, pp. 56–57).[19] On the other hand, freely distributing emission permits could potentially lead to corrupt behaviour (World Bank, 2010, p. 268).[20]

A pure carbon tax fixes the price of carbon, but allows the amount of carbon emissions to vary; and a pure carbon cap places a limit on carbon emissions, letting the market price of tradable carbon allowances vary. Proponents argue that a carbon tax is easier to enforce on a broad-base scale than cap-and-trade programs. The simplicity and immediacy of a carbon tax has been proven effective in British Columbia, Canada – enacted and implemented in five months. Taxing can provide the right incentives for polluters, inventors, and engineers to develop cleaner technologies, in addition to creating revenue for the government. [21] A hybrid cap-and-trade program puts a limit on price increases and, in some cases, sets a floor price as well. The upper limit is set by adding more allowances to the market at a set price while the floor price is maintained by not allowing sales into the market at a price below the floor.[22] The Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative, for example, sets an upper limit on allowance prices through its cost containment provision.

Supporters of carbon cap-and-trade systems believe it sets legal limits for emissions reductions, unlike with carbon taxes. Most cap and trade programs have a descending cap, usually a fixed percentage every year, which gives certainty to the market and guarantees that emissions will decline over time. With a tax, there can be estimates of reduction in carbon emissions, which may not be sufficient to change the course of climate change. A declining cap gives allowance for firm reduction targets and a system for measuring when targets are met. It also allows for flexibility, unlike rigid taxes.[21] Providing emission permits (also called allowances) under emissions trading is preferred in situations where a more accurate target level of emissions certainty is needed.[23]

Eco-tariffs[]

One of the controversies about carbon mitigation policy is how to "level the playing field" with border adjustments.[24] For example, one component of the American Clean Energy and Security Act (a 2009 bill that did not pass), along with several other energy bills put before US Congress, calls for carbon surcharges on goods imported from countries without cap-and-trade programs. Besides issues of compliance with the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, such border adjustments presume that the producing countries bear responsibility for the carbon emissions.

A general perception among developing countries is that discussion of climate change in trade negotiations could lead to "green protectionism" by high-income countries (World Bank, 2010, p. 251).[25] Tariffs on imports ("virtual carbon") consistent with a carbon price of $50 per ton of CO2 could be significant for developing countries. World Bank (2010) commented that introducing border tariffs could lead to a proliferation of trade measures where the competitive playing field is viewed as being uneven. Tariffs could also be a burden on low-income countries that have contributed very little to the problem of climate change.

Carbon leakage[]

Carbon leakage is the effect that regulation of emissions in one country/sector has on the emissions in other countries/sectors that are not subject to the same regulation.[26] There is no consensus over the magnitude of long-term carbon leakage.[27]

The leakage rate is defined as the increase in CO2 emissions outside the countries taking domestic mitigation action, divided by the reduction in emissions of countries taking domestic mitigation action. Accordingly, a leakage rate greater than 100% means that actions to reduce emissions within countries had the effect of increasing emissions in other countries to a greater extent, i.e., domestic mitigation action had actually led to an increase in global emissions.

Estimates of leakage rates for action under the Kyoto Protocol ranged from 5% to 20% as a result of a loss in price competitiveness, but these leakage rates were considered very uncertain.[26] For energy-intensive industries, the beneficial effects of Annex I actions through technological development were considered possibly substantial. However, this beneficial effect had not been reliably quantified. On the empirical evidence they assessed, Barker et al. (2007) concluded that the competitive losses of then-current mitigation actions, e.g., the EU-ETS, were not significant.

Under the EU ETS rules Carbon Leakage Exposure Factor is used to determine the volumes of free allocation of emission permits to industrial installations.


Carbon emission trading systems and markets[]

For emissions trading where greenhouse gases are regulated, one emissions permit is considered equivalent to one tonne of carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions. Other emissions permits are carbon credits, Kyoto units, assigned amount units, and Certified Emission Reduction units (CER). These permits can be sold privately or in the international market at the prevailing market price. These trade and settle internationally, and hence allow permits to be transferred between countries. Each international transfer is validated by the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). Each transfer of ownership within the European Union is additionally validated by the European Commission.

Emissions trading programmes such as the European Union Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) complement the country-to-country trading stipulated in the Kyoto Protocol by allowing private trading of permits. Under such programmes – which are generally co-ordinated with the national emissions targets provided within the framework of the Kyoto Protocol – a national or international authority allocates permits to individual companies based on established criteria, with a view to meeting national and/or regional Kyoto targets at the lowest overall economic cost.[28]

Other greenhouse gases can also be traded, but are quoted as standard multiples of carbon dioxide with respect to their global warming potential. These features reduce the quota's financial impact on business, while ensuring that the quotas are met at a national and international level.

Currently, there are six exchanges trading in UNFCCC related carbon credits: the Chicago Climate Exchange (until 2010[29]), European Climate Exchange, NASDAQ OMX Commodities Europe, PowerNext, Commodity Exchange Bratislava and the European Energy Exchange. NASDAQ OMX Commodities Europe listed a contract to trade offsets generated by a CDM carbon project called Certified Emission Reductions. Many companies now engage in emissions abatement, offsetting, and sequestration programs to generate credits that can be sold on one of the exchanges. At least one private electronic market has been established in 2008: CantorCO2e.[30] Carbon credits at Commodity Exchange Bratislava are traded at special platform called Carbon place.[31]

Trading in emission permits is one of the fastest-growing segments in financial services in the City of London with a market estimated to be worth about €30 billion in 2007. Louis Redshaw, head of environmental markets at Barclays Capital, predicts that "carbon will be the world's biggest commodity market, and it could become the world's biggest market overall."[32] Various proposals for linking international systems across markets are being investigated, and this is being coordinated by the International Carbon Action Partnership (ICAP).[33]

China[]

The Chinese national carbon trading scheme is the largest in the world. It is an intensity-based trading system for carbon dioxide emissions by China, which started operating in 2021.[34]The initial design of the system targets a scope of 3.5 billion tons of carbon dioxide emissions that come from 1700 installations.[35] It has made a voluntary pledge under the UNFCCC to lower CO2 per unit of GDP by 40 to 45% in 2020 when comparing to the 2005 levels.[36]

In November 2011, China approved pilot tests of carbon trading in seven provinces and cities – Beijing, Chongqing, Shanghai, Shenzhen, Tianjin as well as Guangdong Province and Hubei Province, with different prices in each region.[37] The pilot is intended to test the waters and provide valuable lessons for the design of a national system in the near future. Their successes or failures will, therefore, have far-reaching implications for carbon market development in China in terms of trust in a national carbon trading market. Some of the pilot regions can start trading as early as 2013/2014.[38] National trading is expected to start in 2017, latest in 2020.

The effort to start a national trading system has faced some problems that took longer than expected to solve, mainly in the complicated process of initial data collection to determine the base level of pollution emission.[39] According to the initial design, there will be eight sectors that are first included in the trading system: chemicals, petrochemicals, iron and steel, non-ferrous metals, building materials, paper, power and aviation, but many of the companies involved lacked consistent data.[35] Therefore, by the end of 2017, the allocation of emission quotas have started but it has been limited to only the power sector and will gradually expand, although the operation of the market is yet to begin.[40] In this system, Companies that are involved will be asked to meet target level of reduction and the level will contract gradually.[35]

European Union[]

European Allowance prices from 2009

The European Union Emission Trading Scheme (or EU-ETS) is the largest multi-national, greenhouse gas emissions trading scheme in the world. After voluntary trials in the UK and Denmark, Phase I began operation in January 2005 with all 15 member states of the European Union participating.[41] The program caps the amount of carbon dioxide that can be emitted from large installations with a net heat supply in excess of 20 MW, such as power plants and carbon intensive factories,[42] and covers almost half (46%) of the EU's Carbon Dioxide emissions.[43] Phase I permits participants to trade among themselves and in validated credits from the developing world through Kyoto's Clean Development Mechanism. Credits are gained by investing in clean technologies and low-carbon solutions, and by certain types of emission-saving projects around the world to cover a proportion of their emissions.[44]

During Phases I and II, allowances for emissions have typically been given free to firms, which has resulted in them getting windfall profits.[45] Ellerman and Buchner (2008) suggested that during its first two years in operation, the turned an expected increase in emissions of 1%–2% per year into a small absolute decline. Grubb et al. (2009) suggested that a reasonable estimate for the emissions cut achieved during its first two years of operation was 50–100 MtCO2 per year, or 2.5%–5%.[46]

A number of design flaws have limited the effectiveness of the scheme.[47] In the initial 2005–07 period, emission caps were not tight enough to drive a significant reduction in emissions.[45] The total allocation of allowances turned out to exceed actual emissions. This drove the carbon price down to zero in 2007. This oversupply was caused because the allocation of allowances by the EU was based on emissions data from the European Environmental Agency in Copenhagen, which uses a horizontal activity-based emissions definition similar to the United Nations, the EU-ETS Transaction log in Brussels, but a vertical installation-based emissions measurement system. This caused an oversupply of 200 million tonnes (10% of market) in the EU-ETS in the first phase and collapsing prices.[48]

Phase II saw some tightening, but the use of JI and CDM offsets was allowed, with the result that no reductions in the EU will be required to meet the Phase II cap.[45] For Phase II, the cap is expected to result in an emissions reduction in 2010 of about 2.4% compared to expected emissions without the cap (business-as-usual emissions).[47] For Phase III (2013–20), the European Commission proposed a number of changes, including:

  • Setting an overall EU cap, with allowances then allocated;
  • Tighter limits on the use of offsets;
  • Unlimited banking of allowances between Phases II and III;
  • A move from allowances to auction.

In January 2008, Norway, Iceland, and Liechtenstein joined the European Union Emissions Trading System (), according to a publication from the European Commission.[49] The Norwegian Ministry of the Environment has also released its draft National Allocation Plan which provides a carbon cap-and-trade of 15 million tonnes of CO2, 8 million of which are set to be auctioned.[50] According to the OECD Economic Survey of Norway 2010, the nation "has announced a target for 2008–12 10% below its commitment under the Kyoto Protocol and a 30% cut compared with 1990 by 2020."[51] In 2012, EU-15 emissions was 15.1% below their base year level. Based on figures for 2012 by the European Environment Agency, EU-15 emissions averaged 11.8% below base-year levels during the 2008–2012 period. This means the EU-15 over-achieved its first Kyoto target by a wide margin.[52]

A 2020 study found that the European Union Emissions Trading System successfully reduced CO2 emissions even though the prices for carbon were set at low prices.[53]

India[]

Trading is set to begin in 2014 after a three-year rollout period. It is a mandatory energy efficiency trading scheme covering eight sectors responsible for 54 per cent of India's industrial energy consumption. India has pledged a 20 to 25 per cent reduction in emissions intensity from 2005 levels by 2020. Under the scheme, annual efficiency targets will be allocated to firms. Tradable energy-saving permits will be issued depending on the amount of energy saved during a target year.[38]

USA[]

As of 2017, there is no national emissions trading scheme in the United States. Failing to get Congressional approval for such a scheme, President Barack Obama instead acted through the United States Environmental Protection Agency to attempt to adopt through rulemaking the Clean Power Plan, which does not feature emissions trading. The plan was subsequently challenged by the administration of President Donald Trump.

Concerned at the lack of federal action, several states on the east and west coasts have created sub-national cap-and-trade programs.

President Barack Obama in his proposed 2010 United States federal budget wanted to support clean energy development with a 10-year investment of US$15 billion per year, generated from the sale of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions credits. Under the proposed cap-and-trade program, all GHG emissions credits would have been auctioned off, generating an estimated $78.7 billion in additional revenue in FY 2012, steadily increasing to $83 billion by FY 2019.[54] The proposal was never made law.

The American Clean Energy and Security Act (H.R. 2454), a greenhouse gas cap-and-trade bill, was passed on 26 June 2009, in the House of Representatives by a vote of 219–212. The bill originated in the House Energy and Commerce Committee and was introduced by Representatives Henry A. Waxman and Edward J. Markey.[55] The political advocacy organizations FreedomWorks and Americans for Prosperity, funded by brothers David and Charles Koch of Koch Industries, encouraged the Tea Party movement to focus on defeating the legislation.[56][57] Although cap and trade also gained a significant foothold in the Senate via the efforts of Republican Lindsey Graham, Independent and former Democrat Joe Lieberman, and Democrat John Kerry,[58] the legislation died in the Senate.[59]

State and regional programs[]

In 2003, New York State proposed and attained commitments from nine Northeast states to form a cap-and-trade carbon dioxide emissions program for power generators, called the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI). This program launched on January 1, 2009 with the aim to reduce the carbon "budget" of each state's electricity generation sector to 10% below their 2009 allowances by 2018.[60]

Also in 2003, U.S. corporations were able to trade CO2 emission allowances on the Chicago Climate Exchange under a voluntary scheme. In August 2007, the Exchange announced a mechanism to create emission offsets for projects within the United States that cleanly destroy ozone-depleting substances.[61]

In 2006, the California Legislature passed the California Global Warming Solutions Act, AB-32. Thus far, flexible mechanisms in the form of project based offsets have been suggested for three main project types. The project types include: manure management, forestry, and destruction of ozone-depleted substances. However, a ruling from Judge Ernest H. Goldsmith of San Francisco's Superior Court stated that the rules governing California's cap-and-trade system were adopted without a proper analysis of alternative methods to reduce greenhouse gas emissions.[62] The tentative ruling, issued on January 24, 2011, argued that the California Air Resources Board violated state environmental law by failing to consider such alternatives. If the decision is made final, the state would not be allowed to implement its proposed cap-and-trade system until the California Air Resources Board fully complies with the California Environmental Quality Act.[63] However, on June 24, 2011, the Superior Court's ruling was overturned by the Court of Appeals.[64] By 2012, some of the emitters obtained allowances for free, which is for the electric utilities, industrial facilities and natural gas distributors, whereas some of the others have to go to the auction.[65] The California cap-and-trade program came into effect in 2013.

In 2014, the Texas legislature approved a 10% reduction for the Highly Reactive Volatile Organic Compound (HRVOC) emission limit.[66] This was followed by a 5% reduction for each subsequent year until a total of 25% percent reduction was achieved in 2017.[66]

In February 2007, five U.S. states and four Canadian provinces joined together to create the Western Climate Initiative (WCI), a regional greenhouse gas emissions trading system.[67] In July 2010, a meeting took place to further outline the cap-and-trade system.[68] In November 2011, Arizona, Montana, New Mexico, Oregon, Utah and Washington withdrew from the WCI.[69][70] As of 2021, only the U.S. state of California and the Canadian province of Quebec participate in the WCI.[71]

In 1997, the State of Illinois adopted a trading program for volatile organic compounds in most of the Chicago area, called the Emissions Reduction Market System.[72] Beginning in 2000, over 100 major sources of pollution in eight Illinois counties began trading pollution credits.

Australia[]

In 2003 the New South Wales (NSW) state government unilaterally established the New South Wales Greenhouse Gas Abatement Scheme[73] to reduce emissions by requiring electricity generators and large consumers to purchase NSW Greenhouse Abatement Certificates (NGACs). This has prompted the rollout of free energy-efficient compact fluorescent lightbulbs and other energy-efficiency measures, funded by the credits. This scheme has been criticised by the Centre for Energy and Environmental Markets (CEEM) of the UNSW because of its lack of effectiveness in reducing emissions, its lack of transparency and its lack of verification of the additionality of emission reductions.[74]

Both the incumbent Howard Coalition government and the Rudd Labor opposition promised to implement an emissions trading scheme (ETS) before the 2007 federal election. Labor won the election, with the new government proceeding to implement an ETS. The government introduced the Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme, which the Liberals supported with Malcolm Turnbull as leader. Tony Abbott questioned an ETS, saying the best way to reduce emissions is with a "simple tax".[75] Shortly before the carbon vote, Abbott defeated Turnbull in a leadership challenge, and from there on the Liberals opposed the ETS. This left the government unable to secure passage of the bill and it was subsequently withdrawn.

Julia Gillard defeated Rudd in a leadership challenge and promised not to introduce a carbon tax, but would look to legislate a price on carbon[76] when taking the government to the 2010 election. In the first hung parliament result in 70 years, the government required the support of crossbenchers including the Greens. One requirement for Greens support was a carbon price, which Gillard proceeded with in forming a minority government. A fixed carbon price would proceed to a floating-price ETS within a few years under the plan. The fixed price lent itself to characterisation as a carbon tax and when the government proposed the Clean Energy Bill in February 2011,[77] the opposition claimed it to be a broken election promise.[78]

The bill was passed by the Lower House in October 2011[79] and the Upper House in November 2011.[80] The Liberal Party vowed to overturn the bill if elected.[81] The bill thus resulted in passage of the Clean Energy Act, which possessed a great deal of flexibility in its design and uncertainty over its future.

The Liberal/National coalition government elected in September 2013 has promised to reverse the climate legislation of the previous government.[82] In July 2014, the carbon tax was repealed as well as the Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) that was to start in 2015.[83]

Canada[]

The Canadian provinces of Quebec and Nova Scotia operate an emissions trading scheme. Quebec links its program with the US state of California through the Western Climate Initiative.

Japan[]

The Japanese city of Tokyo is like a country in its own right in terms of its energy consumption and GDP. Tokyo consumes as much energy as "entire countries in Northern Europe, and its production matches the GNP of the world's 16th largest country". A scheme to limit carbon emissions launched in April 2010 covers the top 1,400 emitters in Tokyo, and is enforced and overseen by the Tokyo Metropolitan Government.[84][85] Phase 1, which is similar to Japan's scheme, ran until 2015. (Japan had an ineffective voluntary emissions reductions system for years,[86] but no nationwide cap-and-trade program.) Emitters must cut their emissions by 6% or 8% depending on the type of organization; from 2011, those who exceed their limits must buy matching allowances or invest in renewable-energy certificates or offset credits issued by smaller businesses or branch offices.[87] Polluters that fail to comply will be fined up to 500,000 yen plus credits for 1.3 times excess emissions.[88] In its fourth year, emissions were reduced by 23% compared to base-year emissions.[89] In phase 2, (FY2015-FY2019), the target is expected to increase to 15%–17%. The aim is to cut Tokyo's carbon emissions by 25% from 2000 levels by 2020.[87] These emission limits can be met by using technologies such as solar panels and advanced fuel-saving devices.[85]

New Zealand[]

New Zealand Unit Prices

The New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (NZ ETS) is a partial-coverage all-free allocation uncapped highly internationally linked emissions trading scheme. The NZ ETS was first legislated in the Climate Change Response (Emissions Trading) Amendment Act 2008 in September 2008 under the Fifth Labour Government of New Zealand[90][91] and then amended in November 2009[92] and in November 2012[93] by the Fifth National Government of New Zealand.

The NZ ETS covers forestry (a net sink), energy (43.4% of total 2010 emissions), industry (6.7% of total 2010 emissions) and waste (2.8% of total 2010 emissions) but not pastoral agriculture (47% of 2010 total emissions).[94] Participants in the NZ ETS must surrender two emissions units (either an international 'Kyoto' unit or a New Zealand-issued unit) for every three tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent emissions reported or they may choose to buy NZ units from the government at a fixed price of NZ$25.[95]

Individual sectors of the economy have different entry dates when their obligations to report emissions and surrender emission units take effect. Forestry, which contributed net removals of 17.5 Mts of CO2e in 2010 (19% of NZ's 2008 emissions,[96]) entered the NZ ETS on 1 January 2008.[97] The stationary energy, industrial processes and liquid fossil fuel sectors entered the NZ ETS on 1 July 2010. The waste sector (landfill operators) entered on 1 January 2013.[98] Methane and nitrous oxide emissions from pastoral agriculture are not included in the NZ ETS. (From November 2009, agriculture was to enter the NZ ETS on 1 January 2015[95])

The NZ ETS is highly linked to international carbon markets as it allows the importing of most of the Kyoto Protocol emission units. However, as of June 2015, the scheme will effectively transition into a domestic scheme, with restricted access to international Kyoto units (CERs, ERUs and RMUs).[99] The NZ ETS has a domestic unit; the 'New Zealand Unit' (NZU), which is issued by free allocation to emitters, with no auctions intended in the short term.[100] Free allocation of NZUs varies between sectors. The commercial fishery sector (who are not participants) have a free allocation of units on a historic basis.[95] Owners of pre-1990 forests have received a fixed free allocation of units.[97] Free allocation to emissions-intensive industry,[101][102] is provided on an output-intensity basis. For this sector, there is no set limit on the number of units that may be allocated.[103] The number of units allocated to eligible emitters is based on the average emissions per unit of output within a defined 'activity'.[104] Bertram and Terry (2010, p 16) state that as the NZ ETS does not 'cap' emissions, the NZ ETS is not a cap and trade scheme as understood in the economics literature.[105]

Some stakeholders have criticized the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme for its generous free allocations of emission units and the lack of a carbon price signal (the Parliamentary Commissioner for the Environment),[106] and for being ineffective in reducing emissions (Greenpeace Aotearoa New Zealand).[107]

The NZ ETS was reviewed in late 2011 by an independent panel, which reported to the Government and public in September 2011.[108]

South Korea[]

South Korea's national emissions trading scheme officially launched on 1 January 2015, covering 525 entities from 23 sectors. With a three-year cap of 1.8687 billion tCO2e, it now forms the second largest carbon market in the world following the EU ETS. This amounts to roughly two-thirds of the country's emissions. The Korean emissions trading scheme is part of the Republic of Korea's efforts to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by 30% compared to the business-as-usual scenario by 2020.[109]

United Kingdom[]

Business in the UK have come out strongly in support of emissions trading as a key tool to mitigate climate change, supported by NGOs.[110] However, not all businesses favor a trading approach. On December 11, 2008, Rex Tillerson, the CEO of ExxonMobil, said a carbon tax is "a more direct, more transparent and more effective approach" than a cap-and-trade program, which he said, "inevitably introduces unnecessary cost and complexity". He also said that he hoped that the revenues from a carbon tax would be used to lower other taxes so as to be revenue neutral.[111]


Market trend[]

Carbon taxes and emission trading worldwide
Emissions trading and carbon taxes around the world (2021)[112]
  Carbon tax implemented or scheduled
  Carbon emission trading implemented or scheduled
  Carbon emission trading or carbon tax under consideration

Carbon emissions trading increased rapidly in 2021 with the start of the Chinese national carbon trading scheme.[113] The increasing costs of permits on the EU ETS have had the effect of increasing costs of coal power.[114]

A 2019 study by the American Council for an Energy Efficient Economy (ACEEE) finds that efforts to put a price on greenhouse gas emissions are growing in North America. "In addition to carbon taxes in effect in Alberta, British Columbia and Boulder, Colorado, cap and trade programs are in effect in California, Quebec, Nova Scotia and the nine northeastern states that form the Regional Greenhouse gas Initiative (RGGI). Several other states and provinces are currently considering putting a price on emissions."[115]

Business reaction[]

23 multinational corporations came together in the G8 Climate Change Roundtable, a business group formed at the January 2005 World Economic Forum. The group included Ford, Toyota, British Airways, BP and Unilever. On June 9, 2005 the Group published a statement stating the need to act on climate change and stressing the importance of market-based solutions. It called on governments to establish "clear, transparent, and consistent price signals" through "creation of a long-term policy framework" that would include all major producers of greenhouse gases.[116] By December 2007, this had grown to encompass 150 global businesses.[117]

The International Air Transport Association, whose 230 member airlines comprise 93% of all international traffic, position is that trading should be based on "benchmarking", setting emissions levels based on industry averages, rather than "grandfathering", which would use individual companies' previous emissions levels to set their future permit allowances. They argue grandfathering "would penalise airlines that took early action to modernise their fleets, while a benchmarking approach, if designed properly, would reward more efficient operations".[118]

In 2021 shipowners said they are against being included in the EU ETS.[119]

Voluntary surrender of units[]

There are examples of individuals and organisations purchasing tradable emission permits and 'retiring' (cancelling) them so they cannot be used by emitters to authorise their emissions. This makes the emissions 'cap' lower and therefore further reduces emissions. It is argued that this removes the credits from the carbon market so they cannot be used to allow the emission of carbon and that this reduces the 'cap' on emissions by reducing the number of credits available to emitters.[120]

Criticisms[]

Critics of carbon trading, such as Carbon Trade Watch, argue that it places disproportionate emphasis on individual lifestyles and carbon footprints, distracting attention from the wider, systemic changes and collective political action that needs to be taken to tackle climate change.[121][full citation needed] Groups such as the Corner House have argued that the market will choose the easiest means to save a given quantity of carbon in the short term, which may be different from the pathway required to obtain sustained and sizable reductions over a longer period, and so a market-led approach is likely to reinforce technological lock-in. For instance, small cuts may often be achieved cheaply through investment in making a technology more efficient, where larger cuts would require scrapping the technology and using a different one. They also argue that emissions trading is undermining alternative approaches to pollution control[clarification needed] with which it does not combine well, and so the overall effect it is having is to actually stall significant change to less polluting technologies. In September 2010, campaigning group FERN released "Trading Carbon: How it works and why it is controversial" [122][full citation needed]which compiles many of the arguments against carbon trading.

The Financial Times published an article about cap-and-trade systems which argued that "Carbon markets create a muddle" and "...leave much room for unverifiable manipulation".[123] Lohmann (2009) pointed out that emissions trading schemes create new uncertainties and risks,[vague] which can be commodified by means of derivatives, thereby creating a new speculative market.[124][clarification needed]

In China some companies started artificial production of greenhouse gases with sole purpose of their recycling and gaining carbon credits. Similar practices happened in India. Earned credit were then sold to companies in US and Europe.[125][126]

Proposals for alternative schemes to avoid the problems of cap-and-trade schemes include Cap and Share,[clarification needed] which was considered by the Irish Parliament in 2008, and the Sky Trust schemes.[127] These schemes stated that cap-and-trade schemes inherently impact the poor and those in rural areas, who have less choice in energy consumption options.

Carbon trading has been criticised as a form of colonialism, in which rich countries maintain their levels of consumption while getting credit for carbon savings in inefficient industrial projects.[128] Nations that have fewer financial resources may find that they cannot afford the permits necessary for developing an industrial infrastructure, thus inhibiting these countries economic development.

The Kyoto Protocol's Clean Development Mechanism has been criticised for not promoting enough sustainable development.

Another criticism is the claimed possibility of non-existent emission reductions being recorded under the Kyoto Protocol due to the surplus of allowances that some countries possess. For example, Russia had a surplus of allowances due to its economic collapse following the end of the Soviet Union.[128] Other countries could have bought these allowances from Russia, but this would not have reduced emissions. Rather, it would have been simply be a redistribution of emissions allowances. In practice, Kyoto Parties have as yet chosen not to buy these surplus allowances.[129]

Flexibility, and thus complexity, inherent in cap and trade schemes has resulted in a great deal of policy uncertainty surrounding these schemes. Such uncertainty has beset such schemes in Australia, Canada, China, the EU, India, Japan, New Zealand, and the US. As a result of this uncertainty, organizations have little incentive to innovate and comply, resulting in an ongoing battle of stakeholder contestation for the past two decades.[130]

Lohmann (2006b) supported conventional regulation, green taxes, and energy policies that are "justice-based" and "community-driven."[131] According to Carbon Trade Watch (2009), carbon trading has had a "disastrous track record." The effectiveness of the EU ETS was criticized, and it was argued that the CDM had routinely favoured "environmentally ineffective and socially unjust projects."[132]

Annie Leonard's 2009 documentary The Story of Cap and Trade criticized carbon emissions trading for the free permits to major polluters giving them unjust advantages, cheating in connection with carbon offsets, and as a distraction from the search for other solutions.[133]

Offsets[]

Forest campaigner Jutta Kill (2006) of European environmental group FERN argued that offsets for emission reductions were not substitute for actual cuts in emissions. Kill stated that "[carbon] in trees is temporary: Trees can easily release carbon into the atmosphere through fire, disease, climatic changes, natural decay and timber harvesting."[134]

Permit supply level[]

Regulatory agencies run the risk of issuing too many emission credits, which can result in a very low price on emission permits.[45] This reduces the incentive that permit-liable firms have to cut back their emissions. On the other hand, issuing too few permits can result in an excessively high permit price.[135] This is an argument for a hybrid instrument having a price-floor, i.e., a minimum permit price, and a price-ceiling, i.e., a limit on the permit price. However, a price-ceiling (safety value) removes the certainty of a particular quantity limit of emissions.[136]

Permit allocation versus auctioning[]

If polluters receive emission permits for free ("grandfathering"), this may be a reason for them not to cut their emissions because if they do they will receive fewer permits in the future.[137]

This perverse incentive can be alleviated if permits are auctioned, i.e., sold to polluters, rather than giving them the permits for free.[135] Auctioning is a method for distributing emission allowances in a cap-and-trade system whereby allowances are sold to the highest bidder. Revenues from auctioning go to the government and can be used for development of sustainable technology[138] or to cut distortionary taxes, thus improving the efficiency of the overall cap policy.[139]

On the other hand, allocating permits can be used as a measure to protect domestic firms who are internationally exposed to competition.[135] This happens when domestic firms compete against other firms that are not subject to the same regulation. This argument in favor of allocation of permits has been used in the EU ETS, where industries that have been judged to be internationally exposed, e.g., cement and steel production, have been given permits for free).[140]

Structuring issues[]

Corporate and governmental carbon emission trading schemes have been modified in ways that have been attributed to permitting money laundering to take place.[141][142] The principal point here is that financial system innovations (outside banking) open up the possibility for unregulated (non-banking) transactions to take place in relativity unsupervised markets.

Public opinion[]

In the United States, most polling shows large support for emissions trading (often referred to as cap-and-trade). This majority support can be seen in polls conducted by The Washington Post/ABC News,[143] Zogby International[144] and Yale University.[145] A new Washington Post-ABC poll reveals that majorities of the American people believe in climate change, are concerned about it, are willing to change their lifestyles and pay more to address it, and want the federal government to regulate greenhouse gases. They are, however, ambivalent on cap-and-trade.[146]

More than three-quarters of respondents, 77.0%, reported they "strongly support" (51.0%) or "somewhat support" (26.0%) the EPA's decision to regulate carbon emissions. While 68.6% of respondents reported being "very willing" (23.0%) or "somewhat willing" (45.6%), another 26.8% reported being "somewhat unwilling" (8.8%) or "not at all willing" (18.0%) to pay higher prices for "Green" energy sources to support funding for programs that reduce the effect of global warming.[146]

According to PolitiFact, it is a misconception that emissions trading is unpopular in the United States because of earlier polls from Zogby International and Rasmussen which misleadingly include "new taxes" in the questions (taxes aren't part of emissions trading) or high energy cost estimates.[147]

See also[]

References[]

  1. ^ Olivier & Peters 2020, p. 12
  2. ^ ICAP 2021
  3. ^ "Policy Brief: EU emissions trading". Mercator Research Institute on Global Commons and Climate Change. Retrieved August 8, 2021.
  4. ^ Yuan, Lin. "China's national carbon market exceeds expectations". Retrieved August 8, 2021.
  5. ^ "Carbon Price Viewer". EMBER.
  6. ^ Matthey, Astrid; Bünger, Björn (February 11, 2019). Methodological Convention 3.0 for the Assessment of Environmental Costs (PDF) (Report). German Environment Agency. p. 8.
  7. ^ Grimeaud, D, 'An overview of the policy and legal aspects of the international climate change regime' (2001) 9(2) Environmental Liability 39.
  8. ^ Stewart, R, "Economic incentives for environmental protection: opportunities and obstacles", in Revesz, R; Sands, P; Stewart, R (eds.), Environment Law, the Economy and Sustainable Development, 2000, Cambridge University Press.
  9. ^ IMF (March 2008). "Fiscal Implications of Climate Change" (PDF). International Monetary Fund, Fiscal Affairs Department. Retrieved April 26, 2010.
  10. ^ Halsnæs, K.; et al. (2007). "2.4 Cost and benefit concepts, including private and social cost perspectives and relationships to other decision-making frameworks". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Framing issues. Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. p. 6. Archived from the original on May 2, 2010. Retrieved April 26, 2010.
  11. ^ Toth, F.L.; et al. (2005). "10.1.2.2 The Problem Is Long Term.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Decision-making Frameworks. Climate Change 2005: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. Archived from the original on December 7, 2013. Retrieved January 10, 2010.
  12. ^ Smith, J.B.; et al. (2005). "19.5.1. Aggregate Analysis: An Assessment. In (book chapter): Vulnerability to Climate Change and Reasons for Concern: A Synthesis. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.J. McCarthy et al. Eds.)". Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. Archived from the original on February 24, 2010. Retrieved January 10, 2010.
  13. ^ Toth, F.L.; et al. (2001). "10.4.7 Emerging Conclusions with Respect to Policy-relevant Scientific Questions. In (book chapter): Decision-making Frameworks. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. Eds.)". Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. Archived from the original on August 5, 2009. Retrieved January 10, 2010.
  14. ^ Arrow, K.J.; et al. (1996). Intertemporal Equity, Discounting, and Economic Efficiency. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.P. Bruce et al. Eds.) (PDF). This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. PDF version: Prof. Joseph Stiglitz's web page at Columbia University. pp. 125–144. Archived from the original (PDF) on May 15, 2011. Retrieved February 11, 2010.
  15. ^ Smith, J.B.; et al. (2001). "19.4.1. Analysis of Distributional Incidence: State of the Art. In (book chapter): Vulnerability to Climate Change and Reasons for Concern: A Synthesis. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.J. McCarthy et al. Eds.)". Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. Archived from the original on June 5, 2011. Retrieved April 26, 2010.
  16. ^ Smith, J.B.; et al. (2001). "19.8.2.3. Aggregate Impacts. In (book chapter): Vulnerability to Climate Change and Reasons for Concern: A Synthesis. In: Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.J. McCarthy et al. Eds.)". Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. Archived from the original on February 24, 2010. Retrieved April 26, 2010.
  17. ^ Carbon Trust (March 2009). "Memorandum submitted by The Carbon Trust (ET19). Environmental Audit Committee – Fourth Report: The role of carbon markets in preventing dangerous climate charge. Session 2009–10". UK Parliament website. Retrieved April 26, 2010.
  18. ^ Bashmakov, I.; et al. (2001). "6.1.5.1 Key Lessons from the Political Economy Literature.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Chapter 6. Policies, Measures, and Instruments. Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. Archived from the original on August 5, 2009. Retrieved April 26, 2010.
  19. ^ Smith, S. (June 11, 2008). "Environmentally Related Taxes and Tradable Permit Systems in Practice" (PDF). OECD, Environment Directorate, Centre for Tax Policy and Administration. Retrieved April 26, 2010.
  20. ^ World Bank (2010). "World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change" (PDF). The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433. Retrieved November 12, 2014.
  21. ^ Jump up to: a b Beinecke, Frances; Sachs, Jeffrey D.; Krupp, Fred; Pielke Jr., Roger A.; Stavins, Robert N.; Komanoff, Charles; Claussen, Eileen; Fischhoff, Baruch (May 7, 2009). "Putting a Price on Carbon: An Emissions Cap or a Tax? by". Yale Environment 360. Archived from the original on August 2, 2010. Retrieved August 6, 2010.
  22. ^ "Carbon Pricing 101". Union of Concerned Scientists. Retrieved October 11, 2019.
  23. ^ Trade and climate change: WTO-UNEP Report. Geneve: WTO. 2009.
  24. ^ Houser, Trevor; Rob Bradley; Britt Childs Staley; Jake Werksman; Robert Heilmayr (2008). Leveling The Carbon Playing Field: International Competition and U.S. Climate Policy Design. Peterson Institute for International Economics.
  25. ^ "World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change" (PDF). World Bank. 2010. Retrieved April 6, 2010.
  26. ^ Jump up to: a b Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. IPCC. Archived from the original on June 8, 2011. Retrieved April 5, 2010.
  27. ^ Goldemberg, J.; et al. (1996). "Introduction: scope of the assessment" (PDF). In J.P. Bruce; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. IPCC. p. 31. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8.
  28. ^ "Tax Treaty Issues Related to Emissions Permits/Credits" (PDF). OECD. Retrieved November 22, 2014.
  29. ^ Lavelle, Marianne (November 3, 2010). "A U.S. Cap-And-Trade Experiment to End". National Geographic. Retrieved November 7, 2010.
  30. ^ "CantorCO2e Launches First Internet CER Auction" (Press release). CantorCO2e. September 9, 2008. Archived from the original on May 1, 2011. Retrieved January 27, 2010.
  31. ^ "Carbon Place . EU – Market with carbon credits – EUA, CER, ERU, VER, AAU-S, AAU-G". Retrieved September 25, 2015.
  32. ^ Kanter, James (June 20, 2007). "Carbon trading: Where greed is green". The New York Times. Retrieved January 27, 2010.
  33. ^ International Carbon Action Partnership.
  34. ^ "China National ETS".
  35. ^ Jump up to: a b c "China Looks Towards Next Steps For Implementing National Carbon Market". ICTSD. January 18, 2018. Archived from the original on September 8, 2018.
  36. ^ "China could launch national carbon market in 2016". CLIMATE HOME.
  37. ^ Andrews-Speed, Philip (November 2014). "China's Energy Policymaking Processes and Their Consequences". The National Bureau of Asian Research Energy Security Report. Retrieved December 24, 2014.
  38. ^ Jump up to: a b "Factbox: Carbon trading schemes around the world". Reuters. Archived from the original on September 24, 2015. Retrieved September 25, 2015.
  39. ^ Feng, Emily (December 19, 2017). "China moves towards launch of carbon trading scheme". Financial Times.
  40. ^ "China to Launch World's Largest Emissions Trading System". UNFCCC. December 19, 2017.
  41. ^ Climate Change: The European Union's Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) Archived August 30, 2006, at the Wayback Machine
  42. ^ "Britain, California to join forces on global warming". The Washington Times. July 31, 2006. Retrieved November 3, 2009.
  43. ^ Wagner, M. Firms, the Framework Convention on Climate Change & the EU Emissions Trading System Archived 2017-04-25 at the Wayback Machine. Lüneburg: Centre for Sustainability Management 2004, p. 12.
  44. ^ "The EU Emissions Trading System (EU-ETS)"
  45. ^ Jump up to: a b c d "Chapter 4: Carbon markets and carbon price". Building a low-carbon economy – The UK's contribution to tackling climate change. Committee on Climate Change. December 2008. pp. 140–149. Retrieved April 26, 2010.
  46. ^ Grubb, M.; et al. (August 3, 2009). "Climate Policy and Industrial Competitiveness: Ten Insights from Europe on the EU Emissions Trading System" (PDF). Climate Strategies. p. 11. Retrieved April 25, 2017.
  47. ^ Jump up to: a b Jones, B.; et al. (October 2007). "Appendix 1.2 Climate Change: Economic Impact and Policy Responses". World Economic and Financial Surveys, World Economic Outlook, Globalization and Inequality. IMF: 64. Retrieved April 26, 2010. Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  48. ^ Kanen, J.L.M. "Carbon Trading & Prcing". Fulton Publishing (December 2006), pp. 68–69.
  49. ^ "EU action against climate change" (PDF). European Commission. 2007. p. 24. Retrieved April 25, 2017.
  50. ^ Norwegian Ministry of the Environment (2007). "The Norwegian Government accepts to include the EU Emissions Trading Directive in the EEA agreement". European Commission. p. 24. Retrieved August 3, 2010.
  51. ^ "Economic Survey of Norway 2010: Sustainable development: climate change and fisheries policies". Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. 2010. Retrieved April 25, 2017.
  52. ^ "EU greenhouse gas emissions and targets". European Commission. Retrieved October 23, 2014.
  53. ^ Bayer, Patrick; Aklin, Michaël (April 2, 2020). "The European Union Emissions Trading System reduced CO2 emissions despite low prices". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 117 (16): 8804–8812. doi:10.1073/pnas.1918128117. ISSN 0027-8424. PMC 7183178. PMID 32253304.
  54. ^ "President's Budget Draws Clean Energy Funds from Climate Measure". Renewable Energy World. Retrieved April 3, 2009.
  55. ^ "The American Clean Energy and Security Act (H.R. 2454)". Energycommerce.house.gov. June 1, 2009. Retrieved June 14, 2010.
  56. ^ Dryzek, John S.; Norgaard, Richard B.; Schlosberg, David (2011). The Oxford Handbook of Climate Change and Society. Oxford University Press. p. 154. ISBN 9780199683420.
  57. ^ Mayer, Jane (August 30, 2010). "Covert Operations: The billionaire brothers who are waging a war against Obama". The New Yorker. Retrieved March 20, 2015.
  58. ^ Lizza, Ryan (October 11, 2010). "As the World Burns: How the Senate and the White House missed their best chance to deal with climate change". The New Yorker.
  59. ^ Turin, Dustin R. (2012). "The Challenges of Climate Change Policy: Explaining the Failure of Cap and Trade in the United States With a Multiple-Streams Framework". Student Pulse. 4 (6).
  60. ^ Memorandum of Understanding Archived 2011-05-11 at the Wayback Machine – Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative
  61. ^ Brüning, Kristian; Cohen, Jeff (March 7, 2008). "Beyond the Kyoto six". Carbon Finance. Fulton Publishing. Archived from the original on July 27, 2011. Retrieved July 26, 2011.
  62. ^ Barringer, Felicity (February 4, 2011). "California Law to Curb Greenhouse Gases Faces a Legal Hurdle". The New York Times. Retrieved February 9, 2011.
  63. ^ Buchanan, Wyatt (February 4, 2011). "Calif. cap-trade plan dealt blow by S.F. judge". San Francisco Chronicle. Archived from the original on February 8, 2011. Retrieved February 9, 2011.
  64. ^ "Cap and Trade Regulations Approved and Transmitted; Preliminary List of Covered Entities Now Available". Retrieved June 23, 2021.
  65. ^ Summary of California's Cap and Trade Program Archived 2016-11-10 at the Wayback Machine, Center for Climate and Energy Solutions.
  66. ^ Jump up to: a b "Highly Reactive Volatile Organic Compound Emissions Cap and Trade Program". TCEQ. Retrieved November 30, 2017.
  67. ^ Western Climate Initiative Archived 2008-04-23 at the Wayback Machine.
  68. ^ "California, New Mexico and 3 Canadian provinces outline regional cap-and-trade program", Los Angeles Times, 28 July 2010.
  69. ^ "Six US states leave the Western Climate Initiative" (18 November 2011). S&P Global Platts. Retrieved 2016-11-26.
  70. ^ "6 States Pull Out of Western Climate Initiative" (22 November 2011). SustainableBusiness.com News. Retrieved 2016-11-26.
  71. ^ The Canadian province of Nova Scotia is a member of the WCI, but its carbon market is not linked to that of California and Quebec.
  72. ^ "Emissions Reduction Market System What Is ERMS?". Illinois EPA. 2007. Archived from the original on November 28, 2014. Retrieved September 22, 2005.
  73. ^ "The Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme". NSW: Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme Administrator. January 4, 2010. Retrieved January 16, 2010.
  74. ^ Passey, Rob; MacGill, Iain; Outhred, Hugh (2007). "The NSW Greenhouse Gas Reduction Scheme: An analysis of the NGAC Registry for the 2003, 2004 and 2005 Compliance Periods" (PDF). CEEM discussion paper DP_070822. Sydney: The UNSW Centre for Energy and Environmental Markets (CEEM). Archived from the original (PDF) on September 29, 2009. Retrieved November 3, 2009. Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  75. ^ "Abbott defends carbon tax interview". ABC News. June 7, 2011. Retrieved September 25, 2015.
  76. ^ "Julia Gillard's carbon price promise", The Australian, 20 August 2010.
  77. ^ Leslie, Tim (February 24, 2011). "Gillard unveils Carbon Price Details". ABC News.
  78. ^ Hudson, Phillip (February 26, 2011). "Tony Abbott calls for election on carbon tax". Herald Sun. Retrieved May 5, 2011.
  79. ^ Johnston, Matt (October 12, 2011). "Carbon tax bills pass lower house of federal Parliament". Herald Sun. Retrieved October 12, 2011.
  80. ^ AAP with Reuters (November 8, 2011). "Carbon tax gets green light in Senate". Sydney Morning Herald.
  81. ^ "Opposition vows to repeal carbon tax". Sydney Morning Herald. October 2, 2011.
  82. ^ "Abbott Government's first actions: trash climate change education, carbon pricing", Indymedia Australia, 20 September 2013. Accessed 8 November 2013.
  83. ^ "Carbon tax scrapped: PM Tony Abbott sees key election promise fulfilled after Senate votes for repeal". ABC News. July 17, 2014. Retrieved September 25, 2015.
  84. ^ "Tokyo Metropolitan Government Leads Japan, Launches Own GHG Emissions Cap-and-Trade Program". Artcraft Japan. July 16, 2010. Retrieved August 5, 2010.
  85. ^ Jump up to: a b China's Carbon Emission Trading, 2012.
  86. ^ "Tokyo CO2 credit trading plan may become a model". Reuters. February 11, 2010. Retrieved April 25, 2017.
  87. ^ Jump up to: a b Business Green (April 8, 2010). "Tokyo kicks off carbon trading scheme". The Guardian. Retrieved December 29, 2010.
  88. ^ "Urban Environment and Climate Change – Publications". Retrieved September 25, 2015.
  89. ^ "Emissions Trading Worldwide ICAP Status Report 2015" (PDF).
  90. ^ Parker, David (September 10, 2008). "Historic climate change legislation passes". New Zealand Government Media Release. Archived from the original on September 26, 2008. Retrieved September 10, 2008.
  91. ^ "Climate Change Response (Emissions Trading) Amendment Act 2008 No 85". www.legislation.govt.nz. Parliamentary Counsel Office. September 25, 2008. Retrieved January 25, 2010.
  92. ^ Hon Nick Smith (November 25, 2009). "Balanced new law important step on climate change". New Zealand Government Press Release. Retrieved June 14, 2010.
  93. ^ "ETS Amendment Bill passes third reading" (Press release). New Zealand Government. November 9, 2012. Retrieved November 12, 2012.
  94. ^ "New Zealand's Greenhouse Gas Inventory 1990–2010 and Net Position Snapshot". Ministry for the Environment. October 2012. Archived from the original on October 24, 2012. Retrieved November 10, 2012.
  95. ^ Jump up to: a b c "Summary of the proposed changes to the NZ ETS". Emissions trading bulletin No 11. Ministry for the Environment. September 2009. Archived from the original on May 19, 2010. Retrieved May 15, 2010.
  96. ^ "New Zealand's Greenhouse Gas Inventory 1990–2008". ME 1009. Ministry for the Environment. April 2010. ISSN 1179-223X. Archived from the original on April 21, 2010. Retrieved May 22, 2010.
  97. ^ Jump up to: a b "How will the changes impact on forestry?". Questions and answers about amendments to the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS). Ministry for the Environment. January 14, 2010. Archived from the original on May 14, 2010. Retrieved May 16, 2010.
  98. ^ "Waste – New Zealand Climate change information". Ministry for the Environment. July 15, 2011. Archived from the original on July 11, 2011. Retrieved July 26, 2011.
  99. ^ "Emissions Trading Worldwide ICAP Status Report 2015" (PDF). ICAP. February 10, 2015. Retrieved March 16, 2015.
  100. ^ "New Zealand Units (NZUs)". Climate change information New Zealand. Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government (www.climatechange.govt.nz). June 18, 2010. Archived from the original on August 9, 2010. Retrieved August 13, 2010. In the short term, the Government is unlikely to sell emission units because the Kyoto units allocated to New Zealand will be needed to support New Zealand's international obligations, as well as allocation to eligible sectors under the emissions trading scheme.
  101. ^ "Who will get a free allocation of emission units?". Questions and answers about the emissions trading scheme. Ministry for the Environment, NZ Government. January 14, 2010. Archived from the original on May 14, 2010. Retrieved May 15, 2010.
  102. ^ "Agriculture". Summary of the proposed changes to the NZ ETS – Emissions Trading Bulletin 11. Ministry for the Environment. September 2009. Archived from the original on May 19, 2010. Retrieved May 16, 2010.
  103. ^ "Industrial allocation update". Emissions trading bulletin No 12, INFO 441. Ministry for the Environment, NZ. September 2009. Archived from the original on June 5, 2010. Retrieved August 8, 2010. The Bill changes the allocation provisions of the existing CCRA from allocating a fixed pool of emissions to an uncapped approach to allocation. There is no longer an explicit limit on the number of New Zealand units (NZUs) that can be allocated to the industrial sector.
  104. ^ "How will free allocation of emission units to the industrial sector work now?". Questions and answers about amendments to the New Zealand Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS). Ministry for the Environment. January 14, 2010. Archived from the original on June 28, 2010. Retrieved May 16, 2010.
  105. ^ Bertram, Geoff; Terry, Simon (2010). The Carbon Challenge: New Zealand's Emissions Trading Scheme. Bridget Williams Books, Wellington. ISBN 978-1-877242-46-5. The New Zealand ETS does not fit this model because there is no cap and therefore no certainty as to the volume of emissions with which the national economy must operate
  106. ^ "New bill 'weakens ETS' says Environment Commissioner" (Press release). Parliamentary Commissioner for the Environment. October 15, 2009. Retrieved October 15, 2009. The allocation of free carbon credits to industrial processes is extremely generous and removes the carbon price signal where New Zealand needs one the most
  107. ^ "Revised ETS an insult to New Zealanders" (Press release). Greenpeace New Zealand. September 14, 2009. Retrieved October 12, 2009. We now have on the table a pathetic ETS which won't actually do anything to reduce emissions
  108. ^ "Issues statement for public consultation". NZ ETS Review 2011. Ministry for the Environment. April 21, 2011. Archived from the original on November 17, 2011. Retrieved November 4, 2011.
  109. ^ "Emissions Trading Worldwide ICAP Status Report 2015" (PDF).
  110. ^ "UK Position on the EU Emissions Trading Scheme" (PDF). Meeting the Energy Challenge. UK Department of Trade and Industry. May 2007. Archived from the original on June 9, 2009. Retrieved April 25, 2017.CS1 maint: bot: original URL status unknown (link)
  111. ^ "Exxon supports carbon tax". Calgary Herald News. January 9, 2009. Archived from the original on January 22, 2009.
  112. ^ Bank, World (May 25, 2021), State and Trends of Carbon Pricing 2021, World Bank, retrieved July 7, 2021
  113. ^ "China's carbon market scheme too limited, say analysts". www.ft.com. Retrieved July 16, 2021.
  114. ^ "Study: EU emission trading system makes coal more expensive". CompressorTECH2. June 24, 2021. Retrieved July 16, 2021.
  115. ^ eschwass (January 2, 2019). "State and Provincial Efforts to Put a Price on Greenhouse Gas Emissions, with Implications for Energy Efficiency". ACEEE. Retrieved January 8, 2019.
  116. ^ "Statement of G8 Climate Change Roundtable" (PDF). World Economic Forum. June 9, 2005. Archived from the original (PDF) on May 8, 2013.
  117. ^ List of climate leaders EPA December 12
  118. ^ "What You Need to Know About Emissions Trading" (PDF). International Air Transport Association. Archived from the original (PDF) on March 3, 2007. Retrieved September 26, 2009.
  119. ^ Meredith, Sam (July 12, 2021). "The world's largest carbon market is set for a historic revamp. Europe's shipowners are concerned". CNBC. Retrieved July 16, 2021.
  120. ^ "Strengthening the ETS". Climakind (www.climakind.com). 2010. Retrieved February 21, 2010.
  121. ^ "Carbon Trade Watch".
  122. ^ "Trading Carbon".
  123. ^ "Carbon markets create a muddle". Financial Times. April 26, 2007. Archived from the original on May 7, 2015. Retrieved April 3, 2009.
  124. ^ Larry Lohmann: Uncertainty Markets and Carbon Markets. Variations on Polanyian Themes, New Political Economy, first published August 2009, abstract and full text
  125. ^ Carbon-Credits System Tarnished by WikiLeaks Revelation
  126. ^ Imminent EU proposals to clamp down on fridge gas scam
  127. ^ Ray Barrell, Alan Barrett, Noel Casserly, Frank Convery, Jean Goggin, Ide Kearney, Simon Kirby, Pete Lunn, Martin O'Brien and Lisa Ryan. 2009. Budget Perspectives, Tim Callan (ed.)
  128. ^ Jump up to: a b Liverman, D.M. (2008). "Conventions of climate change: constructions of danger and the dispossession of the atmosphere" (PDF). Journal of Historical Geography. 35 (2): 279–296. doi:10.1016/j.jhg.2008.08.008. Archived from the original (PDF) on December 4, 2009. Retrieved August 8, 2009.
  129. ^ PBL (October 16, 2009). "Industrialised countries will collectively meet 2010 Kyoto target". Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency (PBL) website. Archived from the original on April 9, 2010. Retrieved April 26, 2010.
  130. ^ Teeter, Preston; Sandberg, Jorgen (2016). "Constraining or Enabling Green Capability Development? How Policy Uncertainty Affects Organizational Responses to Flexible Environmental Regulations" (PDF). British Journal of Management. 28 (4): 649–665. doi:10.1111/1467-8551.12188. S2CID 157986703.
  131. ^ Lohmann, Larry (2006b). "Ways forward (The Corner House)". The Corner House. Retrieved April 3, 2009.
  132. ^ Carbon Trade Watch (November 2009). "Carbon Trading – How it works and why it fails". Dag Hammarskjöld Foundation. Archived from the original on August 25, 2017. Retrieved August 4, 2010.
  133. ^ Annie Leonard (2009). "The Story of Cap and Trade". The Story of Stuff Project. Archived from the original on November 3, 2010. Retrieved October 31, 2010.
  134. ^ Kill, J. (July 2006). "10 things you should know about tree 'offsets'". New Internationalist. Retrieved April 28, 2010.
  135. ^ Jump up to: a b c Hepburn, C. (2006). "Regulating by prices, quantities or both: an update and an overview" (PDF). Oxford Review of Economic Policy. 22 (2): 236–239. doi:10.1093/oxrep/grj014. Archived from the original (PDF) on January 14, 2009. Retrieved August 30, 2009.
  136. ^ Bashmakov, I.; et al. (2001). "6. Policies, Measures, and Instruments". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. IPCC. Archived from the original on August 5, 2009. Retrieved April 26, 2010.
  137. ^ "Fiscal Implications of Climate Change" (PDF). International Monetary Fund. March 2008. pp. 25–26. Retrieved April 26, 2010.
  138. ^ "Climate change; The greening of America". The Economist. January 25, 2007. Archived from the original on February 12, 2009. Retrieved April 3, 2009.
  139. ^ Fisher, B.S.; et al. (1996). "An Economic Assessment of Policy Instruments for Combating Climate Change" (PDF). In J.P. Bruce; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. IPCC. p. 417. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8.
  140. ^ Cambridge Centre for Climate Change Mitigation Research (June 19, 2008). "The Revision of the EU's Emissions Trading System". UK Parliament. Retrieved April 28, 2010.
  141. ^ "Carbon trading used as money-laundering front: experts" www.saigon-gpdaily.com.vn Archived August 28, 2010, at the Wayback Machine
  142. ^ I. Lippert. Enacting Environments: An Ethnography of the Digitalisation and Naturalisation of Emissions. University of Augsburg, 2013.
  143. ^ "Majority of Poll Respondents Say U.S. Should Limit Greenhouse Gases", The Washington Post. 25 June 2009.
  144. ^ "Poll Position: New Zogby Poll Shows 71% Support for Waxman-Markey", The Wall Street Journal. 11 Aug. 2009
  145. ^ "Poll: Americans Support Strong Climate, Energy Policies",Yale Climate & Energy Institute Archived 2012-01-28 at the Wayback Machine
  146. ^ Jump up to: a b Roberts, David (June 26, 2009). "What can we learn from polls on cap-and-trade?". Grist. Retrieved October 27, 2014.
  147. ^ "IBD editorial board claims that cap-and-trade is unpopular in America", PolitiFact

Other sources[]

Further reading[]

External links[]

Retrieved from ""