Economics of climate change mitigation
This article's lead section may be too short to adequately summarize the key points. (November 2020) |
The economics of climate change mitigation is the part of the economics of climate change related to climate change mitigation, that is actions that are designed to limit the amount of long-term climate change.[2] Mitigation may be achieved through the reduction of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions or through the enhancement of sinks that absorb GHGs, for example forests.
Definitions[]
In this article, the phrase "climate change" is used to describe a change in the climate, measured in terms of its statistical properties, e.g., the global mean surface temperature.[3] In this context, “climate” is taken to mean the average weather. Climate can change over period of time ranging from months to thousands or millions of years. The classical time period is 30 years, as defined by the World Meteorological Organization. The climate change referred to may be due to natural causes, e.g., changes in the sun's output, or due human activities, e.g., changing the composition of the atmosphere.[4] Any human-induced changes in climate will occur against the "background" of natural climatic variations (see attribution of recent climate change for more information).
Public good issues[]
The atmosphere is an international public good and GHG emissions are an international externality.[5] A change in the quality of the atmosphere does not affect the welfare of all individuals and countries equally. In other words, some individuals and countries may benefit[page needed] from climate change, but others may lose out.[6]
Heterogeneity[]
GHG emissions are unevenly distributed around the world, as are the potential impacts of climate change. Nations with higher than average emissions that face potentially small negative/positive climate change impacts have little incentive to reduce their emissions. Nations with relatively low levels of emissions that face potentially large negative climate change impacts have a large incentive to reduce emissions.[why?] Nations that avoid mitigation can benefit from free-riding on the actions of others, and may even enjoy gains in trade and/or investment.[7] The unequal distribution of benefits from mitigation, and the potential advantages of free-riding, made it difficult to secure the Paris Agreement, which aims to reduce emissions.
Intergenerational transfers[]
Mitigation of climate change can be considered a transfer of wealth from the present generation to future generations.[8] The amount of mitigation determines the composition of resources (e.g., environmental or material) that future generations receive. Across generations, the costs and benefits of mitigation are not equally shared: future generations potentially benefit from mitigation, while the present generation bear the costs of mitigation but do not directly benefit[9] (ignoring possible co-benefits, such as reduced air pollution). If the current generation also benefitted from mitigation, it might lead them to be more willing to bear the costs of mitigation.
Irreversible impacts and policy[]
Emissions of carbon dioxide (CO
2) might be irreversible on the time scale of millennia.[10] There are risks of irreversible climate changes, and the possibility of sudden changes in climate. Investments made in long-lived, large-scale low-emission technologies are essentially irreversible. If the scientific basis for these investments turns out to be wrong, they would become "stranded" assets. Additionally, the costs of reducing emissions may change over time in a non-linear fashion.
From an economic perspective, as the scale of private sector investment in low-carbon technologies increases, so do the risks.[clarification needed] Uncertainty over future climate policy decisions makes investors reluctant to undertake large-scale investment without upfront government support. The later section on finance discusses how risk affects investment in developing and emerging economies.
Sustainable development[]
This section may be too technical for most readers to understand.(November 2019) |
Solow (1992)[11] defined sustainable development as allowing for reductions in exhaustible resources so long as these reductions are adequately offset by increases in other resources. This definition implicitly assumes that resources can be substituted, a view which is supported by economic history. Another view is that reductions in some exhaustible resources can only be partially made up for by substitutes. If true, this might mean then some assets need to be preserved at all costs.
In many developing countries, Solow's definition might not be viewed as being acceptable, since it could place a constraint on their ambitions for development. A remedy for this would be for developed countries to pay all the costs of mitigation, including costs in developing countries. This solution is suggested by both Rawlsian and utilitarian constructs of the social welfare function. These functions are used to assess the welfare impacts on all individuals of climate change and related policies.[12] The Rawlsian approach concentrates on the welfare of the worst-off in society, whereas the utilitarian approach is a sum of utilities.[11]
It might be argued that since such redistributions of resources are not observed now, why would either Rawlsian or utilitarian constructs be appropriate for climate change[11] A possible response to this would point to the fact that in the absence of government intervention, market rates of redistribution will not equal social rates.
Emissions and economic growth[]
Economic growth is a key driver of CO2 emissions (Sathaye et al., 2007:707).[13] As the economy expands, demand for energy and energy-intensive goods increases, pushing up CO2 emissions. On the other hand, economic growth may drive technological change and increase energy efficiency. Economic growth may be associated with specialization in certain economic sectors. If specialization is in energy-intensive sectors, specifically carbon energy sources, then there will be a strong link between economic growth and emissions growth. If the specialization is in clean energy source there will be a reverse relationship (as carbon energy use reduces) between economic growth and emissions. If specialization is in less energy-intensive sectors, e.g. the services sector, then there might be a weak link between economic growth and emissions growth. Unlike technological change or energy efficiency improvements, specialization in high or low energy intensity sectors does not affect global emissions. Rather, it changes the distribution of global emissions.
Much of the literature focuses on the "environmental Kuznets curve" (EKC) hypothesis, which posits that at early stages of development, pollution per capita and GDP per capita move in the same direction. Beyond a certain income level, emissions per capita will decrease as GDP per capita increase, thus generating an inverted-U shaped relationship between GDP per capita and pollution. Sathaye et al.. (2007) concluded that the econometrics literature did not support either an optimistic interpretation of the EKC hypothesis - i.e., that the problem of emissions growth will solve itself - or a pessimistic interpretation - i.e., that economic growth is irrevocably linked to emissions growth. Instead, it was suggested that there was some degree of flexibility between economic growth and emissions growth.
Policies to reduce emissions[]
Stop subsidizing fossil fuels[]
This section needs expansion with: A summary of the literature on policy prescriptions for subsidies. You can help by . (August 2010) |
Large energy subsidies are present in many countries (Barker et al., 2001:567-568).[14] As of 2019 governments subsidize fossil fuels by about $500 billion per year: however using an unconventional definition of subsidy which includes failing to price greenhouse gas emissions, the International Monetary Fund estimated that fossil fuel subsidies were $5.2 trillion in 2017, which was 6.4% of global GDP.[15] Economic theory indicates that the optimal policy would be to remove coal mining and burning subsidies and replace them with optimal[clarification needed] taxes. Global studies indicate that even without introducing taxes, subsidy and trade barrier removal at a sectoral level would improve efficiency and reduce environmental damage (Barker et al., 2001:568). Removal of these subsidies would substantially[quantify] reduce GHG emissions and create jobs in renewable energy.[16]
The actual effects of removing fossil fuel subsidies would depend heavily on the type of subsidy removed and the availability and economics of other energy sources.[17] There is also the issue of carbon leakage, where removal of a subsidy to an energy-intensive industry could lead to a shift in production to another country with less regulation, and thus to a net increase in global emissions.
In developed countries, energy costs are low and heavily subsidized, whereas in developing countries, the poor pay high costs for low-quality services.[18] Bashmakov et al.. (2001:410) commented on the difficulty of measuring energy subsidies, but found some evidence that coal production subsidies had declined in several developing and OECD countries.[needs update?]
Jacobson and Delucchi (2009) have advanced a plan to power 100% of the world's energy with wind, hydroelectric, and solar power by the year 2030,[19][20] recommending transfer of energy subsidies from fossil fuel to renewable, and a price on carbon reflecting its cost for flood, cyclone, hurricane, drought, and related extreme weather expenses.
Some fossil fuel companies lobby governments.[21]
Price signals[]
This section needs expansion. You can help by . (November 2019) |
Carbon pricing[]
A carbon price is a system of applying a price to carbon emissions, as a method of emissions mitigation.[22] Potential methods of pricing include emission trading, results-based climate finance, crediting mechanisms and more.[23] Carbon pricing can also lend itself to the creation of carbon taxes, which would allow for governments to tax GHG emissions, as a method to benefit the government with a large increase in funding.[22]
Carbon tax[]
Once a government has decided on the price of GHG emissions, they can take that number and use it to set tax rates for businesses (and households, if necessary).[24] Carbon taxes are considered especially useful because, once a number has been created, it will benefit the government either with currency or with a lowering in GHG emissions or even both, and therefore benefit the environment.[24] It is almost a worldwide consensus that carbon taxing is the most cost-effective method of having a substantial and rapid response to climate change and carbon emissions.[25] However, backlash to the tax includes that it could be considered regressive, as the impact from the tax would be damaging disproportionately to the poor who spend much of their income on energy for their homes.[26] Still, even with the near universal approval, there are many questions that are unanswered regarding both the collection and redistribution of the taxes. One of the central questions being how the newly collected taxes will be redistributed.[27]
Some or all of the proceeds of a carbon tax can be used to stop it disadvantaging the poor.[15]
Structural market reforms[]
Market-orientated reforms, as undertaken by several countries in the 1990s, can have important effects on energy use, energy efficiency, and therefore GHG emissions. In a literature assessment, Bashmakov et al.. (2001:409) gave the example of China, which has made structural reforms with the aim of increasing GDP.[28] They found that since 1978, energy use in China had increased by an average of 4% per year, but at the same time, energy use had been reduced per unit of GDP.
Emissions trading[]
In addition to the implementation of command-and-control regulations (as with a carbon tax), governments can also use market-based approaches to mitigate emissions. One such method is emissions trading where governments set the total emissions of all polluters to a maximum and distribute permits, through auction or allocation, that allow entities to emit a portion, typically one ton of carbon dioxide equivalent (CO2e), of the mandated total emissions.[29] In other words, the amount of pollution an entity can emit in an emissions trading system is limited by the number of permits they have. If a polluter wants to increase their emissions, they can only do so after buying permits from those who are willing to sell them.[30] Many economists prefer this method of reducing emissions as it is market based and highly cost effective.[29] That being said, emissions trading alone is not perfect since it fails to place a clear price on emissions. Without this price, emissions prices are volatile due to the supply of permits being fixed, meaning their price is entirely determined by shifts in demand.[31] This uncertainty in price is especially disliked by businesses since it prevents them from investing in abatement technologies with confidence which hinders efforts for mitigating emissions.[31] Regardless, while emissions trading alone has its problems and cannot reduce pollutants to the point of stabilizing the global climate, it remains an important tool for addressing climate change.
Liberalization of energy markets[]
Liberalization and restructuring of energy markets has occurred in several countries and regions, including Africa, the EU, Latin America, and the US. These policies have mainly been designed to increase competition in the market, but they can have a significant impact on emissions. Reform could allow the market to be more responsive to price signals placed on emissions. In 2020 it was estimated that by 2022 replacement of all existing coal-fired power stations by renewables and storage would be profitable in total but that "A key barrier to accelerating phaseout is that the vast majority (93 percent) of global coal plants are insulated from competition from renewables by long-term contracts and noncompetitive tariffs".[32]
Climate and other environmental policies[]
National[]
- Regulatory standards: These set technology or performance standards, and can be effective in addressing the market failure of informational barriers (Bashmakov et al., 2001:412).[28] If the costs of regulation are less than the benefits of addressing the market failure, standards can result in net benefits.
- Emission taxes and charges: an emissions tax requires domestic emitters to pay a fixed fee or tax for every tonne of CO2-eq GHG emissions released into the atmosphere (Bashmakov et al., 2001:413). If every emitter were to face the same level of tax, the lowest cost way of achieving emission reductions in the economy would be undertaken first. In the real world, however, markets are not perfect, meaning that an emissions tax may deviate from this ideal. Distributional and equity considerations usually result in differential tax rates for different sources.
- Tradable permits: Emissions can be limited with a permit system (Bashmakov et al., 2001:415). A number of permits are distributed equal to the emission limit, with each liable entity required to hold the number of permits equal to its actual emissions. A tradable permit system can be cost-effective so long as transaction costs are not excessive, and there are no significant imperfections in the permit market and markets relating to emitting activities.
- Voluntary agreements: These are agreements between government and industry (Bashmakov et al., 2001:417). Agreements may relate to general issues, such as research and development, but in other cases, quantitative targets may be agreed upon. An advantage of voluntary agreements are their low transaction costs. There is, however, the risk that participants in the agreement will free ride, either by not complying with the agreement or by benefitting from the agreement while bearing no cost.
- Informational instruments: According to Bashmakov et al.. (2001:419), poor information is recognized as a barrier to improved energy efficiency or reduced emissions. Examples of policies in this area include increasing public awareness of climate change, e.g., through advertising, and the funding of climate change research.
- Environmental subsidies: A subsidy for GHG emissions reductions pays entities a specific amount per tonne of CO2-eq for every tonne of GHG reduced or sequestered (Bashmakov et al., 2001:421). Although subsidies are generally less efficient than taxes, distributional and competitiveness issues sometimes result in energy/emission taxes being coupled with subsidies or tax exceptions.
- Research and development policies: Government funding of research and development (R&D) on energy has historically favoured nuclear and coal technologies. Bashmakov et al.. (2001:421) found that although research into renewable energy and energy-efficient technologies had increased, it was still a relatively small proportion of R&D budgets in the OECD.
- Green power: The policy ensures that part of the electricity supply comes from designated renewable sources (Bashmakov et al., 2001:422). The cost of compliance is borne by all consumers.
- Demand-side management: This aims to reduce energy demand, e.g., through energy audits, labelling, and regulation (Bashmakov et al., 2001:422).
According to Bashmakov et al.. (2001:422), the most effective and economically efficient approach of achieving lower emissions in the energy sector is to apply a combination of market-based instruments (taxes, permits), standards, and information policies.
International[]
This section needs to be updated. The reason given is: Kyoto being replaced by Paris Agreement - remove excess Kyoto details.(April 2019) |
Kyoto Protocol[]
The Kyoto Protocol is an international treaty designed to reduce emissions of GHGs.[33] The Kyoto treaty was agreed in 1997,[33] and is a protocol to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC), which had previously been agreed in 1992. The Kyoto Protocol sets legally-blinding emissions limitations for developed countries ("Annex I Parties") out to 2008-2012.[33] The US has not ratified the Kyoto Protocol, and its target is therefore non-binding.[34] Canada has ratified the treaty, but withdrew in 2011.[35]
The Kyoto treaty is a "cap-and-trade" system of emissions trading, which includes emissions reductions in developing countries ("non-Annex I Parties") through the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM).[36] The economics of the Kyoto Protocol is discussed in Views on the Kyoto Protocol and Flexible mechanisms#Views on the flexibility mechanisms. Cost estimates for the treaty are summarized at Kyoto Protocol#Cost estimates. Economic analysis of the CDM is available at Clean Development Mechanism.
To summarize, the caps agreed to in Kyoto's first commitment period (2008-2012) have turned out to be too weak.[37] There are a large surplus of emissions allowances in the former-Soviet economies ("Economies-in-Transition" - EITs), while several other OECD countries have a deficit, and are not on course to meet their Kyoto targets (see Kyoto Protocol#Annex I Parties with targets).[34][37] Because of the large surplus of allowances, full trading of Kyoto allowances would likely depress the price of the permits near to zero.[38] Some of the surplus allowances have been bought from the EITs,[39] but overall little trading has taken place.[37][40] Countries have mainly concentrated on meeting their targets domestically, and through the use of the CDM.[41]
Some countries have implemented domestic energy/carbon taxes (see carbon tax for details) and emissions trading schemes (ETSs). The individual articles on the various ETSs contain commentaries on these schemes - see Kyoto Protocol#International Emissions Trading for a list.
A number of analysts have focussed on the need to establish a global price on carbon in order to reduce emissions cost-effectively.[42] The Kyoto treaty does not set a global price for carbon.[43] As stated earlier, the US is not part of the Kyoto treaty, and is a major contributor to global annual emissions of carbon dioxide[44] (see also greenhouse gas#Regional and national attribution of emissions). Additionally, the treaty does not place caps on emissions in developing countries.[43] The lack of caps for developing countries was based on equity (fairness) considerations (see Kyoto Protocol#Negotiations for more information).[45] Developing countries, however, have undertaken a range of policies to reduce their emissions domestically.[46] The later Cancún agreement, agreed under the UNFCCC, is based on voluntary pledges rather than binding commitments.[47]
The UNFCCC has agreed that future global warming should be limited to below 2 °C relative to the pre-industrial temperature.[47] Analyses by the United Nations Environment Programme[48] and International Energy Agency[49] suggest that current policies (as of 2011) are not strong enough to meet this target.
Paris Agreement[]
The Paris Agreement was agreed upon on in December 2015 as the UNFCCC's latest response to global climate change.[50] Ratified in 2016 after receiving signatures from 195 countries as well as the EU that, when combined, make up a large majority of current GHG emissions, the agreement is planned to go underway in 2020.[51] China, the world leader in GHG emissions,[52] as well as the U.S., who withdrew from the Kyoto Protocol,[53] both initially joined the agreement. This effort is a new and aggressive method to reduce these emissions, as a step up from the Kyoto Protocol with more up to date incentives, and a more active role being undertaken by the UNFCCC in reaching their goal.
Goals of the Agreement[]
A main point of distinction between the Kyoto Protocol and the Paris Agreement is that the new agreement is not abandoning the previous one, as it is attempting to build off of it.[50] Several seeds were planted by specialists while the Kyoto Protocol was in effect that would suggest that more action was needed to reach the goal of 2 degrees Celsius or less.[49] The Paris Agreement is, unlike Kyoto, calling upon all countries (developed and developing) to equally aid in their goal of keeping the global temperature from rising by 2 degrees Celsius pre-industrial standard, while actively following efforts to keep that number to below 1.5 degrees Celsius.[50] The UNFCCC aims to accomplish this with aid to all countries, through financial assistance, a new technological framework, among other measures of assistance, while remaining accountable with the implementation of their transparency framework.[54] The Paris Agreement does not give specified instructions on a country-by-country basis, instead opting to have countries propose their own NDCs, or Nationally Decided Contributions, every five years, as to not force or restrict countries efforts.[54] As a result, the UNFCCC (in collaboration with willing developed countries) has to adjust for financial compensation as well as other methods of assistance for developing countries, or countries that require specific forms of assistance.[51]
U.S. withdrawal from the Paris Agreement[]
In 2017, a year after the US was a member of the over 200 countries that ratified the Paris Agreement, President Trump announced that the US would be exiting the deal.[55] The reasoning behind the decision was tied to potential issues with the U.S. economy, as well as the President believing the deal to be unfair for the U.S.[56] President Trump has a complicated history with climate change, quoted as saying that he does not believe in it, while at the same time acknowledging the severity and importance of it.[57] The U.S. decision to withdraw, however, is not official as the process to leave the agreement will take a calendar year by the standards set by the UNFCCC, and will essentially allow for the winner of the 2020 presidential election to have the final say.[55] Some argue that the decision for the US to leave the Paris Agreement will be beneficial to the remaining countries goal by motivating these countries to step-up in the place of the US, while others argue the US would not have reached its targets regardless if it had elected to stay.[58]
Other policies[]
- Regulatory instruments: This could involve the setting of regulatory standards for various products and processes for countries to adopt. The other option is to set national emission limits. The second option leads to inefficiency because the marginal costs of abatement differs between countries (Bashmakov et al.., 2001:430).[28]
Initiatives such as the EU "cap and trade" system have also been implemented.[59]
- Carbon taxes: This would offer a potentially cost-effective means of reducing CO2 emissions. Compared with emissions trading, international or harmonized (where each country keeps the revenue it collects) taxes provide greater certainty about the likely costs of emission reductions. This is also true of a hybrid policy (see the article carbon tax) (Bashmakov et al.., 2001:430).
Efficiency of international agreements[]
For the purposes of analysis, it is possible to separate efficiency from equity (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 30).[5] It has been suggested that because of the low energy efficiency in many developing countries, efforts should first be made in those countries to reduce emissions. Goldemberg et al. (1996, p. 34) suggested a number of policies to improve efficiency, including:
- Property rights reform. For example, deforestation could be reduced through reform of property rights.
- Administrative reforms. For example, in many countries, electricity is priced at the cost of production. Economists, however, recommend that electricity, like any other good, should be priced at the competitive price.[citation needed]
- Regulating non-greenhouse externalities. There are externalities other than the emission of GHGs, for example, road congestion leading to air pollution. Addressing these externalities, e.g., through congestion pricing and energy taxes, could help to lower both air pollution and GHG emissions.
General equilibrium theory
One of the aspects of efficiency for an international agreement on reducing emissions is participation. In order to be efficient, mechanisms to reduce emissions still require all emitters to face the same costs of emission (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 30).[5] Partial participation significantly reduces the effectiveness of policies to reduce emissions. This is because of how the global economy is connected through trade.
General equilibrium theory points to a number of difficulties with partial participation (p. 31). Examples are of "leakage" (carbon leakage) of emissions from countries with regulations on GHG emissions to countries with less regulation. For example, stringent regulation in developed countries could result in polluting industries such as aluminium production moving production to developing countries. Leakage is a type of "spillover" effect of mitigation policies.
Estimates of spillover effects are uncertain (Barker et al., 2007).[60] If mitigation policies are only implemented in Kyoto Annex I countries, some researchers have concluded that spillover effects might render these policies ineffective, or possibly even cause global emissions to increase (Barker et al., 2007).[61] Others have suggested that spillover might be beneficial and result in reduced emission intensities in developing countries.
Comprehensiveness
Efficiency also requires that the costs of emission reductions be minimized (Goldemberg et al., 1996, p. 31). This implies that all GHGs (CO2, methane, etc.) are considered as part of a policy to reduce emissions, and also that carbon sinks are included. Perhaps most controversially, the requirement for efficiency implies that all parts of the Kaya identity are included as part of a mitigation policy. [62]The components of the Kaya identity are:
- CO2 emissions per unit of energy, (carbon intensity)
- energy per unit of output, (energy efficiency)
- economic output per capita,
- and human population.
Efficiency requires that the marginal costs of mitigation for each of these components is equal. In other words, from the perspective of improving the overall efficiency of a long-term mitigation strategy, population control has as much "validity" as efforts made to improve energy efficiency.
Equity in international agreements[]
This section needs to be updated.(November 2019) |
Unlike efficiency, there is no consensus view of how to assess the fairness of a particular climate policy (Bashmakov et al.. 2001:438-439;[28] see also economics of global warming#Paying for an international public good). This does not prevent the study of how a particular policy impacts welfare. Edmonds et al. (1995) estimated that a policy of stabilizing national emissions without trading would, by 2020, shift more than 80% of the aggregate policy costs to non-OECD regions (Bashmakov et al.., 2001:439). A common global carbon tax would result in an uneven burden of abatement costs across the world and would change with time. With a global tradable quota system, welfare impacts would vary according to quota allocation.
Regional aspects[]
This section needs to be updated.(November 2019) |
Climate change mitigation policies can have a large and complex impact, both positive and negative, on the socio-economic status of individuals and countries.[63] Without “well-designed and inclusive policies, climate change mitigation measures can place a higher financial burden on poor households.”[64]
In a literature assessment, Sathaye et al.. (2001:387-389) described regional barriers to mitigation:[65]
- Developing countries:
- In many developing countries, importing mitigation technologies might lead to an increase in their external debt and balance-of-payments deficit.
- Technology transfer to these countries can be hindered by the possibility of non-enforcement of intellectual property rights. This leaves little incentive for private firms to participate. On the other hand, enforcement of property rights can lead to developing countries facing high costs associated with patents and licensing fees.
- A lack of available capital and finance is common in developing countries.. Together with the absence of regulatory standards, this barrier supports the proliferation of inefficient equipment.
- Economies in transition: In the New Independent States, Sathaye et al. (2007) concluded that a lack of liquidity and a weak environmental policy framework were barriers to investment in mitigation.
Finance[]
Article 4.2 of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change commits industrialized countries to "[take] the lead" in reducing emissions.[67] The Kyoto Protocol to the UNFCCC has provided only limited financial support to developing countries to assist them in climate change mitigation and adaptation.[68]:233 Additionally, private sector investment in mitigation and adaptation could be discouraged in the short and medium term because of the 2008 global financial crisis.[69]:xix
The International Energy Agency estimates that US$197 billion is required by states in the developing world above and beyond the underlying investments needed by various sectors regardless of climate considerations, this is twice the amount promised by the developed world at the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) Cancún Agreements.[70] Thus, a new method is being developed to help ensure that funding is available for climate change mitigation.[70] This involves financial leveraging, whereby public financing is used to encourage private investment.[70]
The private sector is often unwilling to finance low carbon technologies in developing and emerging economies as the market incentives are often lacking.[70] There are many perceived risks involved, in particular:[70]
- General political risk associated politically instability, uncertain property rights and an unfamiliar legal framework.[70]
- Currency risks are involved is financing is sought internationally and not provided in the nationally currency.[70]
- Regulatory and policy risk - if the public incentives provided by a state may not be actually provided, or if provided, then not for the full length of the investment.[70]
- Execution risk – reflecting concern that the local project developer/firm may lack the capacity and/or experience to execute the project efficiently.[70]
- Technology risk as new technologies involved in low carbon technology may not work as well as expected.[70]
- Unfamiliarity risks occur when investors have never undertaken such projects before.[70]
Funds from the developed world can help mitigate these risks and thus leverage much larger private funds, the current aim to create $3 of private investment for every $1 of public funds.[71]:4 Public funds can be used to minimise the risks in the following way.[70]
- Loan guarantees provided by international public financial institutions can be useful to reduce the risk to private lenders.[70]
- Policy insurance can insurance the investor against changes or disruption to government policies designed to encourage low carbon technology, such as a feed-in tariff.[70]
- Foreign exchange liquidity facilities can help reduce the risks associated with borrowing money in a different currency by creating a line of credit that can be drawn on when the project needs money as a result of local currency devaluation but then repaid when the project has a financial surplus.[70]
- Pledge fund can help projects are too small for equity investors to consider or unable to access sufficient equity. In this model, public finance sponsors provide a small amount of equity to anchor and encourage much larger pledges from private investors, such as sovereign wealth funds, large private equity firms and pension funds. Private equity investors will tend to be risk-averse and focused primarily on long-term profitability, thus all projects would need to meet the fiduciary requirements of the investors.[70]
- Subordinated equity fund - an alternative use of public finance is through the provision of subordinated equity, meaning that the repayment on the equity is of lower priority than the repayment of other equity investors.[70] The subordinated equity would aim to leverage other equity investors by ensuring that the latter have first claim on the distribution of profit, thereby increasing their risk-adjusted returns.[70] The fund would have claim on profits only after rewards to other equity investors were distributed.[70]
Europe[]
The European Investment Bank plans to support €1 trillion of climate investment by 2030 as part of the European Green Deal.[72] In 2019 the EIB Board of Directors approved new targets for climate action and environmental sustainability to phase out fossil fuel financing.[73][74] The bank will increase the share of its financing for to climate action and environmental sustainability to 50% by 2025 The European Investment Bank Group announced it will align all financing with the Paris Agreement by the end of 2020. The bank aims "to play a leading role in mobilising the finance needed to achieve the worldwide commitment to keep global warming well below 2˚C, aiming for 1.5˚C."[75][76]
Assessing costs and benefits[]
GDP[]
The costs of mitigation and adaptation policies can be measured as a change in GDP. A problem with this method of assessing costs is that GDP is an imperfect measure of welfare (Markandya et al.., 2001:478):[77]
- Not all welfare is included in GDP, e.g., housework and leisure activities.
- There are externalities in the economy which mean that some prices might not be truly reflective of their social costs.
Corrections can be made to GDP estimates to allow for these problems, but they are difficult to calculate. In response to this problem, some have suggested using other methods to assess policy. For example, the United Nations Commission for Sustainable Development has developed a system for "Green" GDP accounting and a list of sustainable development indicators.
Baselines[]
The emissions baseline is, by definition, the emissions that would occur in the absence of policy intervention. Definition of the baseline scenario is critical in the assessment of mitigation costs (Markandya et al.., 2001:469-470).[77] This because the baseline determines the potential for emissions reductions, and the costs of implementing emission reduction policies.
There are several concepts used in the literature over baselines, including the "efficient" and "business-as-usual" (BAU) baseline cases. In the efficient baseline, it is assumed that all resources are being employed efficiently. In the BAU case, it is assumed that future development trends follow those of the past, and no changes in policies will take place. The BAU baseline is often associated with high GHG emissions, and may reflect the continuation of current energy-subsidy policies, or other market failures.
Some high emission BAU baselines imply relatively low net mitigation costs per unit of emissions. If the BAU scenario projects a large growth in emissions, total mitigation costs can be relatively high. Conversely, in an efficient baseline, mitigation costs per unit of emissions can be relatively high, but total mitigation costs low.[clarification needed]
Ancillary impacts[]
These are the secondary or side effects of mitigation policies, and including them in studies can result in higher or lower mitigation cost estimates (Markandya et al.., 2001:455).[77] Reduced mortality and morbidity costs are potentially a major ancillary benefit of mitigation. This benefit is associated with reduced use of fossil fuels, thereby resulting in less air pollution (Barker et al.., 2001:564).[14] There may also be ancillary costs. In developing countries, for example, if policy changes resulted in a relative increase in electricity prices, this could result in more pollution (Markandya et al.., 2001:462).
Flexibility[]
Flexibility is the ability to reduce emissions at the lowest cost. The greater the flexibility that governments allow in their regulatory framework to reduce emissions, the lower the potential costs are for achieving emissions reductions (Markandya et al.., 2001:455).[77]
- "Where" flexibility allows costs to be reduced by allowing emissions to be cut at locations where it is most efficient to do so. For example, the Flexibility Mechanisms of the Kyoto Protocol allow "where" flexibility (Toth et al., 2001:660).[8]
- "When" flexibility potentially lowers costs by allowing reductions to be made at a time when it is most efficient to do so.
Including carbon sinks in a policy framework is another source of flexibility. Tree planting and forestry management actions can increase the capacity of sinks. Soils and other types of vegetation are also potential sinks. There is, however, uncertainty over how net emissions are affected by activities in this area.[77][clarification needed]
No regrets options[]
This section may be too technical for most readers to understand.(November 2019) |
No regret options are social and economic benefits developed under the assumption of taking action and establishing preventative measures in current times without fully knowing what climate change will look like in the future.[78][79]
These are emission reduction options that have net negative costs.[77][clarification needed] The presumption of no regret options affects emission reduction cost estimates.
By convention, estimates of emission reduction costs do not include the benefits of avoided climate change damages. It can be argued that the existence of no regret options implies that there are market and , e.g., lack of information, and that these failures can be corrected without incurring costs larger than the benefits gained. In most cases, studies of the no regret concept have not included all the external and implementation costs of a given policy.
Different studies make different assumptions about how far the economy is from the production frontier (defined as the maximum outputs attainable with the optimal use of available inputs – natural resources, labour, etc.[80] "Bottom-up" studies (which consider specific technological and engineering details of the economy) often assume that in the baseline case, the economy is operating below the production frontier. Where the costs of implementing policies are less than the benefits, a no regret option (negative cost) is identified. "Top-down" approaches, based on macroeconomics, assume that the economy is efficient in the baseline case, with the result that mitigation policies always have a positive cost.[citation needed]
The benefits of coal phase out exceed the costs.[81] Switching from cars by improving walking and cycling infrastructure is either free or beneficial to a country's economy as a whole.[82]
Technology[]
Assumptions about technological development and efficiency in the baseline and mitigation scenarios have a major impact on mitigation costs, in particular in bottom-up studies.[77] The magnitude of potential technological efficiency improvements depends on assumptions about future technological innovation and market penetration rates for these technologies.
Discount rates[]
Assessing climate change impacts and mitigation policies involves a comparison of economic flows that occur in different points in time. The discount rate is used by economists to compare economic effects occurring at different times. Discounting converts future economic impacts into their present-day value. The discount rate is generally positive because resources invested today can, on average, be transformed into more resources later. If climate change mitigation is viewed as an investment, then the return on investment can be used to decide how much should be spent on mitigation.
Integrated assessment models (IAM) are used for to estimate the social cost of carbon. The discount rate is one of the factors used in these models. The IAM frequently used is the Dynamic Integrated Climate-Economy (DICE) model developed by William Nordhaus. The DICE model uses discount rates, uncertainty, and risks to make benefit and cost estimations of climate policies and adapt to the current economic behavior.[83]
The choice of discount rate has a large effect on the result of any climate change cost analysis (Halsnæs et al.., 2007:136).[7] Using too high a discount rate will result in too little investment in mitigation, but using too low a rate will result in too much investment in mitigation. In other words, a high discount rate implies that the present-value of a dollar is worth more than the future-value of a dollar.
Discounting can either be prescriptive or descriptive. The descriptive approach is based on what discount rates are observed in the behaviour of people making every day decisions (the private discount rate) (IPCC, 2007c:813).[80] In the prescriptive approach, a discount rate is chosen based on what is thought to be in the best interests of future generations (the social discount rate).
The descriptive approach can be interpreted[clarification needed] as an effort to maximize the economic resources available to future generations, allowing them to decide how to use those resources (Arrow et al., 1996b:133-134).[11] The prescriptive approach can be interpreted as an effort to do as much as is economically justified[clarification needed] to reduce the risk of climate change.
The DICE model incorporates a descriptive approach, in which discounting reflects actual economic conditions. In a recent[when?] DICE model, DICE-2013R Model, the social cost of carbon is estimated based on the following alternative scenarios: (1) a baseline scenario, when climate change policies have not changed since 2010, (2) an optimal scenario, when climate change policies are optimal (fully implemented and followed), (3) when the optimal scenario does not exceed 2oC limit after 1900 data, (4) when the 2oC limit is an average and not the optimum, (5) when a near-zero (low) discount rate of 0.1% is used (as assumed in the Stern Review), (6) when a near-zero discount rate is also used but with calibrated interest rates, and (7) when a high discount rate of 3.5% is used.[84][needs update]
According to Markandya et al.. (2001:466), discount rates used in assessing mitigation programmes need to at least partly reflect the opportunity costs of capital.[77] In developed countries, Markandya et al.. (2001:466) thought that a discount rate of around 4%-6% was probably justified, while in developing countries, a rate of 10%-12% was cited. The discount rates used in assessing private projects were found to be higher – with potential rates of between 10% and 25%.
When deciding how to discount future climate change impacts, value judgements are necessary (Arrow et al.., 1996b:130). IPCC (2001a:9) found that there was no consensus on the use of long-term discount rates in this area.[85] The prescriptive approach to discounting leads to long-term discount rates of 2-3% in real terms, while the descriptive approach leads to rates of at least 4% after tax - sometimes much higher (Halsnæs et al.., 2007:136).
Even today, it is difficult to agree on an appropriate discount rate. The approach of discounting to be either prescriptive or descriptive stemmed from the views of Nordhaus and Stern. Nordhaus takes on a descriptive approach which "assumes that investments to slow climate change must compete with investments in other areas". While Stern takes on a prescriptive approach in which "leads to the conclusion that any positive pure rate of time preference is unethical".[83]
In Nordhaus' view, his descriptive approach translates that the impact of climate change is slow, thus investments in climate change should be on the same level of competition with other investments. He defines the discount rate to be the rate of return on capital investments. The DICE model uses the estimated market return on capital as the discount rate, around an average of 4%. He argues that a higher discount rate will make future damages look small, thus have less effort to reduce emissions today. A lower discount rate will make future damages look larger, thus put more effort to reduce emissions today.[86]
In Stern's view, the pure rate of time preference is defined as the discount rate in a scenario where present and future generations have equal resources and opportunities.[87] A zero pure rate of time preference in this case would indicate that all generations are treated equally. The future generation do not have a "voice" on today's current policies, so the present generation are morally responsible to treat the future generation in the same manner. He suggests for a lower discount rate in which the present generation should invest in the future to reduce the risks of climate change.
Assumptions are made to support estimating high and low discount rates. These estimates depend on future emissions, climate sensitivity relative to increase in greenhouse gas concentrations, and the seriousness of impacts over time.[88] Long-term climate policies will significantly impact future generations and this is called intergenerational discounting. Factors that make intergenerational discounting complicated include the great uncertainty of economic growth, future generations are affected by today's policies, and private discounting will be affected due to a longer "investment horizon".[89]
Controversy[]
Discounting is a relatively controversial issue in both climate change mitigation and environmental economics due to the ethical implications of valuing future generations less than present ones. Non-economists often find it difficult to grapple with the idea that thousands of dollars of future costs and benefits can be valued at less than a cent in the present after discounting.[90] This devaluation can lead to overconsumption and "strategic ignorance" where individuals choose to ignore information that would prevent the overconsumption of resources.[91] Contrary to this, orthodox economists have likewise provided only ethical or normative arguments of their own, suddenly concerned with equality (and flouting, by their own definition, efficiency) they uncharacteristically argue that it is important to distribute society's resources equitably (but only across time), and since they generally, rightly or wrongly predict positive economic growth, despite global climate change, they argue that current generations should damage the environment in which future generations live so that the current ones can consume and produce more to equalize the (rightly or wrongly) assumed gains to the future from a supposed growing net gdp.[92] That being said, not all economists share this opinion as notable economist Frank Ramsey once described discounting as "ethically indefensible."[92]
One root of this controversy can be attributed to the discrepancies between the time scales environmentalists and corporations/governments view the world with. Environmental processes such as the carbonate-silicate cycle and Milankovitch cycles occur on timescales of thousands of years while economic processes, such as infrastructure investments, occur on time scales as short as thirty years. The difference between these two scales makes balancing both interests, sustainability and efficiency, incredibly difficult.[92]
Implementation[]
Because discounting rates are determined and implemented by individual governments, discounting rates are not unanimous across the globe.[93] They range from percentages as high as 15%, as in the Philippines, to as low as 3%, as in Germany.[93]
United States[]
Discounting in the United States is a complicated area for policy analysis. The discounting rate is not the same for every government agency. As of 1992, the recommended discounting rate from the Environmental Protection Agency is 2-3% while the Office of Management and Budget recommends a discount rate of 7%.[94][93] Further complicating things, these rates are fluid and change every year depending on the administration.[95]
United Kingdom[]
The United Kingdom is one of very few governmental bodies that currently use what is known as a declining discount rate.[96] Declining discount rates are gaining popularity due to the fact that they address the uncertainties in economic growth which allows for greater weight to be placed on future benefits, but the extent to this advantage remains to be proven.[97][98]
Decision analysis[]
This is a quantitative type of analysis that is used to assess different potential decisions. Examples are cost-benefit and cost-effectiveness analysis.[8] In cost-benefit analysis, both costs and benefits are assessed economically. In cost-effectiveness analysis, the benefit-side of the analysis, e.g., a specified ceiling for the atmospheric concentration of GHGs, is not based on economic assessment.
One of the benefits of decision analysis is that the analysis is reproducible. Weaknesses, however, have been citied:[99]
- The decision maker:
- In decision analysis, it is assumed that a single decision maker, with well-order preferences, is present throughout the analysis. In a cost-benefit analysis, the preferences of the decision maker are determined by applying the concepts of "willingness to pay" (WTP) and "willingness to accept" (WTA). These concepts are applied in an attempt to determine the aggregate value that society places on different resources.[77]
- In reality, there is no single decision maker. Different decision makers have different sets of values and preferences, and for this reason, decision analysis cannot yield a universally preferred solution.
- Utility valuation: Many of the outcomes of climate policy decisions are difficult to value.
Arrow et al.. (1996a) concluded that while decision analysis had value, it could not identify a globally optimal policy for mitigation. In determining nationally optimal mitigation policies, the problems of decision analysis were viewed as being less important.
Cost-benefit analysis[]
In an economically efficient mitigation response, the marginal (or incremental) costs of mitigation would be balanced against the marginal benefits[to whom?] of emission reduction. "Marginal" means that the costs and benefits of preventing (abating) the emission of the last unit of CO2-eq are being compared. Units are measured in tonnes of CO2-eq. The marginal benefits are the avoided damages from an additional tonne of carbon (emitted as carbon dioxide) being abated in a given emissions pathway (the social cost of carbon).
A problem with this approach is that the marginal costs and benefits of mitigation are uncertain, particularly with regards to the benefits of mitigation (Munasinghe et al., 1996, p. 159).[100] In the absence of risk aversion, and certainty over the costs and benefits, the optimum level of mitigation would be the point where marginal costs equal marginal benefits. IPCC (2007b:18) concluded that integrated analyses of the costs and benefits of mitigation did not unambiguously suggest an emissions pathway where benefits exceed costs (see economics of global warming#Trade offs).[101]
Damage function
In cost-benefit analysis, the optimal timing of mitigation depends more on the shape of the aggregate damage function than the overall damages of climate change (Fisher et al.., 2007:235).[2] If a damage function is used that shows smooth and regular damages, e.g., a cubic function, the results suggest that emission abatement should be postponed. This is because the benefits of early abatement are outweighed by the benefits of investing in other areas that accelerate economic growth. This result can change if the damage function is changed to include the possibility of catastrophic climate change impacts.
The mitigation portfolio[]
In deciding what role emissions abatement should play in a mitigation portfolio, different arguments have been made in favour of modest and stringent near-term abatement (Toth et al.., 2001:658):[8]
- Modest abatement:
- Modest deployment of improving technologies prevents lock-in to existing, low-productivity technology.
- Beginning with modest emission abatement avoids the premature retirement of existing capital stocks.
- Gradual emission reduction reduces induced sectoral unemployment.
- Reduces the costs of emissions abatement.
- There is little evidence of damages from relatively rapid[clarification needed] climate change in the past.
- Stringent abatement:
- Endogenous (market-induced) change could accelerate development of low-cost technologies.
- Reduces the risk of being forced to make future rapid emission reductions that would require premature capital retirement.
- Welfare losses might be associated with faster rates of emission reduction. If, in the future, a low GHG stabilization target is found to be necessary, early abatement reduces the need for a rapid reduction in emissions.
- Reduces future climate change damages.
- Cutting emissions more quickly reduces the possibility of higher damages caused by faster rates of future climate change.
Cost estimates[]
This section needs to be updated.(April 2019) |
Global costs[]
According to a literature assessment by Barker et al.. (2007:622), mitigation cost estimates depend critically on the baseline (in this case, a reference scenario that the alternative scenario is compared with), the way costs are modelled, and assumptions about future government policy.[102] Fisher et al.. (2007) estimated macroeconomic costs in 2030 for multi-gas mitigation (reducing emissions of carbon dioxide and other GHGs, such as methane) as between a 3% decrease in global GDP to a small increase, relative to baseline. This was for an emissions pathway consistent with atmospheric stabilization of GHGs between 445 and 710 ppm CO2-eq. In 2050, the estimated costs for stabilization between 710 and 445 ppm CO2-eq ranged between a 1% gain to a 5.5% decrease in global GDP, relative to baseline. These cost estimates were supported by a moderate amount of evidence and much agreement in the literature (IPCC, 2007b:11,18).[101]
Macroeconomic cost estimates made by Fisher et al.. (2007:204) were mostly based on models that assumed transparent markets, no transaction costs, and perfect implementation of cost-effective policy measures across all regions throughout the 21st century. According to Fisher et al.. (2007), relaxation of some or all these assumptions would lead to an appreciable increase in cost estimates. On the other hand, IPCC (2007b:8) noted that cost estimates could be reduced by allowing for accelerated technological learning, or the possible use of carbon tax/emission permit revenues to reform national tax systems.[101]
In most of the assessed studies, costs rose for increasingly stringent stabilization targets. In scenarios that had high baseline emissions, mitigation costs were generally higher for comparable stabilization targets. In scenarios with low emissions baselines, mitigation costs were generally lower for comparable stabilization targets.
Distributional effects[]
Regional costs[]
Gupta et al.. (2007:776-777) assessed studies where estimates are given for regional mitigation costs. The conclusions of these studies are as follows:[104]
- Regional abatement costs are largely dependent on the assumed stabilization level and baseline scenario. The allocation of emission allowances/permits is also an important factor, but for most countries, is less important than the stabilization level (Gupta et al., 2007, pp. 776–777).
- Other costs arise from changes in international trade. Fossil fuel-exporting regions are likely to be affected by losses in coal and oil exports compared to baseline, while some regions might experience increased bio-energy (energy derived from biomass) exports (Gupta et al., 2007, pp. 776–777).
- Allocation schemes based on current emissions (i.e., where the most allowances/permits are given to the largest current polluters, and the fewest allowances are given to smallest current polluters) lead to welfare losses for developing countries, while allocation schemes based on a per capita convergence of emissions (i.e., where per capita emissions are equalized) lead to welfare gains for developing countries.
Sectoral costs[]
In a literature assessment, Barker et al. (2001:563-564), predicted that the renewables sector could potentially benefit from mitigation.[14] The coal (and possibly the oil) industry was predicted to potentially lose substantial proportions of output relative to a baseline scenario (Barker et al., 2001, pp. 563–564).
See also[]
- Carbon fee and dividend
- Eco-Tariffs
- Ecotax
- Green economy
- Low-carbon economy
- One Earth Climate Model
Notes[]
- ^ "Extreme weather in the US 1980-2011 - NOAA.gov Search Results". search.usa.gov. Retrieved 25 November 2020.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Fisher, B.S.; et al. (2007). "Issues related to mitigation in the long term context.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ Baede, A.P.M. (ed) (2007). "Glossary A-D". In Solomon, S.; D. Qin; M. Manning; Z. Chen; M. Marquis; K.B. Averyt; M. Tignor; H.L. Miller (eds.). Climate Change 2007: Working Group I: The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. Web version: IPCC website. Archived from the original on 27 September 2016. Retrieved 3 September 2010.CS1 maint: extra text: authors list (link)
- ^ Albritton, D.L.; et al. (2001). "Box 1: What drives changes in climate? In (book section): Technical Summary". In Houghton, J.T.; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2001: Working Group I: The Scientific Basis. Contribution of Working Group I to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. Web version: UNEP/GRID-Arendal website.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c Goldemberg, J.; et al. (1996). "Introduction: scope of the assessment.". In J.P. Bruce; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. pp. 21, 28, 43. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8.
- ^ Manisalidis, Ioannis; Stavropoulou, Elisavet; Stavropoulos, Agathangelos; Bezirtzoglou, Eugenia (20 February 2020). "Environmental and Health Impacts of Air Pollution: A Review". Frontiers in Public Health. 8: 14. doi:10.3389/fpubh.2020.00014. ISSN 2296-2565. PMC 7044178. PMID 32154200.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Halsnæs, K.; et al. (2007). "Framing issues". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. p. 127. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c d Toth, F.L.; et al. (2001). "Decision-making Frameworks". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. pp. 607–609. Archived from the original on 13 October 2012. Retrieved 10 January 2010.
- ^ Page, Edward A. (August 2008). "Distributing the burdens of climate change". Environmental Politics. 17 (4): 556–575. doi:10.1080/09644010802193419. ISSN 0964-4016. S2CID 53385652.
- ^ Halsnæs, K.; et al. (2007). "2.2.3 Irreversibility and the implications for decision-making.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Framing issues. Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. ISBN 978-0-521-88011-4. Archived from the original on 2 November 2018. Retrieved 23 May 2010.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c d Arrow, K.J.; et al. (1996b). Intertemporal Equity, Discounting, and Economic Efficiency. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.P. Bruce et al. (eds.)). This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. PDF version: Prof. Joseph Stiglitz's web page at Columbia University. pp. 125–144. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8. Retrieved 11 February 2010.
- ^ Markandya, A.; et al. (2001). "7.2.2.2 Cost Analysis and Development, Equity, and Sustainability Aspects". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Costing Methodologies. Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: GRID-Arendal website. p. 460. doi:10.2277/0521015022 (inactive 31 May 2021). ISBN 978-0-521-01502-8. Archived from the original on 5 August 2009. Retrieved 10 January 2010.CS1 maint: DOI inactive as of May 2021 (link)
- ^ Sathaye, J.; et al. (2007). "Sustainable Development and Mitigation". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Archived from the original on 2 November 2018. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c Barker, T.; et al. (2001), "Sectoral Costs and Ancillary Benefits of Mitigation.", in B. Metz; et al. (eds.), Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, retrieved 10 January 2010
- ^ Jump up to: a b Irfan, Umair (17 May 2019). "Fossil fuels are underpriced by a whopping $5.2 trillion". Vox. Retrieved 23 November 2019.
- ^ "Fossil Fuel to Clean Energy Subsidy Swaps: How to pay for an energy revolution". IISD. 7 June 2019. Retrieved 23 November 2019.
- ^ Barker; et al. (2001). "9.2.1.2 Reducing Subsidies in the Energy Sector". Climate Change 2001: IPCC Third Assessment Report Working Group III: Mitigation. International Panel on Climate Change. Archived from the original on 5 August 2009. Retrieved 1 September 2010.
- ^ Sustainable access to energy in the Global South : essential technologies and implementation approaches. Hostettler, Silvia,, Gadgil, Ashok,, Hazboun, Eileen,, EPFL-UNESCO Conference on Technologies for Development (2014 : Lausanne, Switzerland). Cham. 8 July 2015. ISBN 978-3-319-20209-9. OCLC 913742250.CS1 maint: others (link)
- ^ Jacobson, M.Z. and Delucchi, M.A. (November 2009) "A Plan to Power 100 Percent of the Planet with Renewables" (originally published as "A Path to Sustainable Energy by 2030") Scientific American 301(5):58-65
- ^ Jacobson, M.Z. (2009) "Review of solutions to global warming, air pollution, and energy security" Energy and Environmental Science 2:148-73 doi 10.1039/b809990c (review)
- ^ Laville, Sandra (24 October 2019). "Fossil fuel big five 'spent €251m lobbying EU' since 2010". The Guardian. ISSN 0261-3077. Retrieved 23 November 2019.
- ^ Jump up to: a b "What is a carbon price and why do we need one?". Grantham Research Institute on climate change and the environment. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ "Understanding carbon pricing". Carbon Pricing Leadership Coalition. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ Jump up to: a b "Which is better: carbon tax or cap-and-trade?". Grantham Research Institute on climate change and the environment. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ Implementing a US carbon tax : challenges and debates. Parry, Ian W. H. (Ian William Holmes), 1965-, Morris, Adele Cecile, 1963-, Williams, Roberton C., 1972-. New York. 2015. ISBN 978-1-138-81415-8. OCLC 891001377.CS1 maint: others (link)
- ^ "Pros and cons of a carbon tax » Yale Climate Connections". Yale Climate Connections. 20 July 2016. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ Chen, Zi-yue; Nie, Pu-yan (1 December 2016). "Effects of carbon tax on social welfare: A case study of China". Applied Energy. 183: 1607–1615. doi:10.1016/j.apenergy.2016.09.111. ISSN 0306-2619.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c d Bashmakov, I.; et al. (2001). "Policies, Measures, and Instruments". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press. Archived from the original on 5 March 2016. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ Jump up to: a b "Cap and Trade: Key Terms Glossary" (PDF). Climate Change 101. Center for Climate and Energy Solutions. January 2011. Archived from the original (PDF) on 5 October 2017. Retrieved 27 October 2014.
- ^ "Which is better: carbon tax or cap-and-trade?". Grantham Research Institute on climate change and the environment. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Goulder, Lawrence; Schein, Andrew (August 2013). "Carbon Taxes vs. Cap and Trade: A Critical Review". NBER Working Paper Series. Cambridge, MA. doi:10.3386/w19338. S2CID 158104668.
- ^ "How To Retire Early". Rocky Mountain Institute. Retrieved 1 July 2020.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) (2011), Kyoto Protocol, UNFCCC
- ^ Jump up to: a b Olivier et al. 2011, p. 25
- ^ StarTribune - Canada formally pulls out of Kyoto Protocol on climate change Archived 21 March 2015 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 4 May 2012.
- ^ Grubb 2003, p. 153
- ^ Jump up to: a b c Carbon Trust 2009, pp. 24–25
- ^ Grubb 2003, p. 164
- ^ World Bank 2011, p. 53
- ^ Figure 1 and Table 1 (World Bank 2011, p. 9), which show the EU ETS as taking up the largest share of the carbon market's value. Firms regulated under the EU ETS are unable to use surplus allowances (AAUs) in meeting their EU caps: Ramming, Ingo (September 2008). "AAU Trading and the Impact on Kyoto and EU Emissions Trading. Before the Flood or Storm in a Tea-cup? (Chapter 34)" (PDF). Greenhouse Gas Market Report 2008 (PDF). International Emissions Trading Association (IETA). pp. 140–142. Retrieved 13 August 2020.
- ^ World Bank 2011, pp. 21–30
- ^ e.g., see: "Sec 22.2: Reducing the costs of mitigation through an efficient international framework, in: Ch 22: Creating a Global Price for Carbon" (PDF), HM Treasury, in Stern 2006, pp. 469–472
- ^ Jump up to: a b "Sec 22.4 Putting efficiency and equity together: The experience of Kyoto, in: Ch 22: Creating a Global Price for Carbon" (PDF), HM Treasury, in Stern 2006, pp. 477–478
- ^ Figure 3.2: Olivier et al. 2011, p. 13
- ^
Banuri, T.; et al., "Ch 1: Setting the Stage: Climate Change and Sustainable Development", Sec 1.3.3 How Has Global Climate Policy Treated Equity? Missing or empty
|title=
(help), in IPCC TAR WG3 2001[dead link] - ^ e.g., see World Bank 2011, pp. 33–38
- ^ Jump up to: a b King, D.; et al. (July 2011), "Copenhagen and Cancun", International climate change negotiations: Key lessons and next steps, Oxford, UK: Smith School of Enterprise and the Environment, University of Oxford, p. 12, doi:10.4210/ssee.pbs.2011.0003 (inactive 31 May 2021), archived from the original on 1 August 2013CS1 maint: DOI inactive as of May 2021 (link) PDF version is also available Archived 13 January 2012 at the Wayback Machine
- ^ United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) (November 2011), "Executive Summary" (PDF), Bridging the Emissions Gap: A UNEP Synthesis Report, Nairobi, Kenya: UNEP, p. 8, ISBN 978-92-807-3229-0. UNEP Stock Number: DEW/1470/NA
- ^ Jump up to: a b International Energy Agency (IEA) (2011), "Executive Summary (English)" (PDF), World Energy Outlook 2011, Paris, France: IEA, p. 2
- ^ Jump up to: a b c "Paris Agreement" (PDF). UNFCCC. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Bodle, R., Donat, L., & Duwe, M. (2016). The paris agreement: Analysis, assessment and outlook. Carbon & Climate Law Review : CCLR, 10(1), 5-22. Retrieved from https://www.ecologic.eu/sites/files/event/2016/ecologic_institute_2016_paris_agreement_assessment.pdf
- ^ Blossom, Thomas C. Frohlich and Liz. "These countries produce the most CO2 emissions". USA TODAY. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ Library, C. N. N. (26 July 2013). "Kyoto Protocol Fast Facts". CNN. Retrieved 12 March 2020.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Miller, S. (2016). 2015 Paris Agreement on Climate Change : Elements and Related Matters. Nova Science Publishers, Inc.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Friedman, Lisa (4 November 2019). "Trump Serves Notice to Quit Paris Climate Agreement". The New York Times. ISSN 0362-4331. Retrieved 11 March 2020.
- ^ Chakraborty, Barnini (1 June 2017). "Paris Agreement on climate change: US withdraws as Trump calls it 'unfair'". Fox News. Retrieved 11 March 2020.
- ^ Cheung, Helier (23 January 2020). "What does Trump actually believe on climate change?". BBC News. Retrieved 11 March 2020.
- ^ Symons-Brown, Bonny (2 June 2017). "Could Trump's exit from the Paris deal actually be a win for the environment?". ABC News. Retrieved 11 March 2020.
- ^ European Commission,2017
- ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "11.7.2 Carbon leakage.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective. Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website. Archived from the original on 3 May 2010. Retrieved 5 April 2010.
- ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007), "11.7.1 The nature and importance of spillover. In (book chapter): Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective.", in B. Metz; et al. (eds.), Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Print version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. This version: IPCC website, archived from the original on 11 May 2010, retrieved 5 April 2010
- ^ "The "Kaya Identity" | METEO 469: From Meteorology to Mitigation: Understanding Global Warming". www.e-education.psu.edu. Retrieved 29 November 2020.
- ^ Markkanen, Sanna; Anger-Kraavi, Annela (9 August 2019). "Social impacts of climate change mitigation policies and their implications for inequality". Climate Policy. 19 (7): 827–844. doi:10.1080/14693062.2019.1596873. ISSN 1469-3062. S2CID 159114098.
- ^ "Social Dimensions of Climate Change". World Bank. Retrieved 20 May 2021.
- ^ Sathaye, J.; et al. (2001). "Barriers, Opportunities, and Market Potential of Technologies and Practices. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz, et al., Eds.)". Cambridge University Press. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ "Energy Transition Investment Hit $500 Billion in 2020 – For First Time". BloombergNEF. (Bloomberg New Energy Finance). 19 January 2021. Archived from the original on 19 January 2021.
- ^ Grubb 2003, p. 144
- ^ Staff of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank (2010). World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change. 1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433, USA: The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank. doi:10.1596/978-0-8213-7987-5. ISBN 978-0-8213-7987-5. Retrieved 6 April 2010.CS1 maint: location (link)
- ^ Department of Economic and Social Affairs of the United Nations Secretariat (2009). "Overview" (PDF). World Economic and Social Survey 2009: Promoting Development, Saving the Planet. New York, USA: Printed by the United Nations, Publishing Section. ISBN 978-92-1-109159-5. Retrieved 2 July 2011.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q r s Jessica Brown and Michael Jacobs 2011. Leveraging private investment: the role of public sector climate finance. London: Overseas Development Institute
- ^ Brown, J. & M. Jacobs (April 2011). "ODI Background Notes: Leveraging private investment: the role of public sector climate finance" (PDF). Odi Background Note. 111 Westminster Bridge Road, London SE1 7JD, UK: Overseas Development Institute (ODI). ISSN 1756-7610. Retrieved 2 July 2011.CS1 maint: location (link)
- ^ Harvey, Fiona; Rankin, Jennifer (9 March 2020). "What is the European Green Deal and will it really cost €1tn?". The Guardian. ISSN 0261-3077. Retrieved 19 August 2020.
- ^ Holger, Dieter (15 November 2019). "European Investment Bank Will End Fossil Fuel Financing". Wall Street Journal. ISSN 0099-9660. Retrieved 19 August 2020.
- ^ "European Investment Bank to phase out fossil fuel financing". the Guardian. 15 November 2019. Retrieved 19 August 2020.
- ^ "EU/China/US climate survey shows public optimism about reversing climate change". European Investment Bank. Retrieved 19 August 2020.
- ^ "Climate action". EIB.org. Retrieved 19 August 2020.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c d e f g h i Markandya, A.; et al. (2001). "Costing Methodologies. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds.]". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. p. 474-476. Retrieved 10 January 2010.
- ^ "No Regrets: Circles of Climate Change Adaptation – Principles and Practices for Responding to Climate Change". Retrieved 20 May 2021.
- ^ Philander, S. George (2012). Encyclopedia of Global Warming & Climate Change. SAGE Publications, Inc. p. 1720. doi:10.4135/9781452218564. ISBN 978-1-4129-9261-9.
- ^ Jump up to: a b IPCC (2007c). "Annex. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (B. Metz et al. Eds.)". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. p. 819. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ "Coal exit benefits outweigh its costs — PIK Research Portal". www.pik-potsdam.de. Retrieved 24 March 2020.
- ^ "The Sixth Carbon Budget Surface Transport" (PDF). UKCCC.
there is zero net cost to the economy of switching from cars to walking and cycling
- ^ Jump up to: a b John Weyant. (2017) Some Contributions of Integrated Assessment Models of Global Climate Change. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 11:1, 115-137
- ^ Nordhaus, William (2014). "Estimates of the Social Cost of Carbon: Concepts and Results from the DICE-2013R Model and Alternative Approaches". Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists. 1: 273–312. doi:10.1086/676035. S2CID 155012348.
- ^ IPCC (2001a). "Summary for Policymakers. In: Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds.]". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Retrieved 10 January 2010.
- ^ Nordhaus, W. (2008) A Question of Balance: Weighing the Options on Global Warming Policies Archived 25 May 2017 at the Wayback Machine Yale University Press pp. 10-11
- ^ Ackerman, F. (2007) Debating Climate Economics: The Stern Review vs. Its Critics Global Development and Environment Institute
- ^ Anthoff, D., R.S.J.Tol, and G.W.Yohe (2009), 'Discounting for Climate Change', Economics -- the Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, 3, (2009-24), pp. 1-24.
- ^ U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) December 2010, Guidelines for Preparing Economic Analyses: Discounting Future Benefits and Costs
- ^ "The Use of Discount Rates" (PDF). European Commission - European Commission. Retrieved 24 August 2020.
- ^ Frederick, Shane; Loewenstein, George; O'Donoghue, Ted (June 2002). "Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review". Journal of Economic Literature. 40 (2): 351–401. doi:10.1257/002205102320161311. ISSN 0022-0515.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c Heal, G. M. (1997). Discounting and climate change. Columbia Business School, Columbia University. OCLC 760924527.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c De Guzman, Franklin Liang, Zhihong Lin, Tun Zhuang, Juzhong. Theory and practice in the choice of social discount rate for cost-benefit analysis : a survey (PDF). Asian Development Bank. pp. 17–18. OCLC 836563664.CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
- ^ United States. Office of Management and Budget. (17 September 2003). Regulatory analysis. Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget. OCLC 54768341.
- ^ "Budget Assumptions" (PDF). whitehouse.gov. 5 November 2019. Retrieved 24 August 2020 – via National Archives.
- ^ Cropper, Maureen L.; Freeman, Mark C.; Groom, Ben; Pizer, William A. (1 May 2014). "Declining Discount Rates". American Economic Review. 104 (5): 538–543. doi:10.1257/aer.104.5.538. ISSN 0002-8282.
- ^ Farber, David A. (7 April 2014). "The Case for Declining Discount Rates | The Regulatory Review". www.theregreview.org. Retrieved 24 August 2020.
- ^ Groom, Ben; Hepburn, Cameron; Koundouri, Phoebe; Pearce, David (1 December 2005). "Declining Discount Rates: The Long and the Short of it". Environmental and Resource Economics. 32 (4): 445–493. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.334.8633. doi:10.1007/s10640-005-4681-y. ISSN 1573-1502. S2CID 17750962.
- ^ Arrow, K.J.; et al. (1996a). Decision-making frameworks for addressing climate change. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.P. Bruce et al. (eds.)). This version: Printed by Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. PDF version: IPCC website. p. 57. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8.
- ^ Munasinghe, M.; et al. (1996). Applicability of Techniques of Cost-Benefit Analysis to Climate Change. In: Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (J.P. Bruce et al. (eds.)). This version: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A.. Web version: IPCC website. doi:10.2277/0521568544. ISBN 978-0-521-56854-8.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c IPCC (2007b). "Summary for Policymakers. In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [B. Metz et al. Eds.]". Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ Barker, T.; et al. (2007). "Mitigation from a cross-sectoral perspective.". In B. Metz; et al. (eds.). In: Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A. Archived from the original on 8 June 2011. Retrieved 20 May 2009.
- ^ "Emissions Gap Report 2020 / Executive Summary" (PDF). UNEP.org. Fig. ES.8: United Nations Environment Programme. 2021. p. XV. Archived (PDF) from the original on 31 July 2021.CS1 maint: location (link)
- ^ Gupta, S.; et al. (2007), "Policies, Instruments and Co-operative Arrangements.", in B. Metz; et al. (eds.), Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, and New York, N.Y., U.S.A., retrieved 20 May 2009
References[]
- Carbon Trust (March 2009), Global Carbon Mechanisms: Emerging lessons and implications (CTC748), Carbon Trust
- Grubb, M. (July–September 2003), "The Economics of the Kyoto Protocol" (PDF), World Economics, 4 (3), archived from the original (PDF) on 17 July 2011
- IPCC TAR WG3 (2001), Metz, B.; Davidson, O.; Swart, R.; Pan, J. (eds.), Climate Change 2001: Mitigation, Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 978-0-521-80769-2, archived from the original on 27 February 2017, retrieved 12 May 2019 (pb: 0-521-01502-2).
- Olivier, J.G.J.; Janssens-Maenhout, G.; Peters, J.A.H.W.; Wilson, J. (21 September 2011), Long-term trend in global CO2 emissions; 2011 report (PDF), The Hague, Netherlands: PBL Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency; Institute for Environment and Sustainability (IES) of the European Commission’s Joint Research Centre (JRC), ISBN 978-90-78645-68-9, archived from the original (PDF) on 21 December 2011, retrieved 8 October 2012. PBL publication number 500253004. JRC Technical Note number JRC65918.
- Stern, N. (2006), Stern Review Report on the Economics of Climate Change (pre-publication edition), London, UK: HM Treasury, archived from the original on 7 April 2010
- World Bank (2011), State and Trends of the Carbon Market Report 2011 (PDF), Washington, DC, USA: World Bank Environment Department, Carbon Finance Unit
External links[]
- The website of IPCC Working Group III (WG III). This body assesses options for mitigating climate change through limiting or preventing greenhouse gas emissions and enhancing activities that remove them from the atmosphere.
- International Scientific Congress[clarification needed] - "Climate Change: Global Risks, Challenges & Decisions", University of Copenhagen. Plenary Session, 11 March 2009, 9.00-10.15. Download video-file: (Windows Media Video-format). Chair: Professor Michael Grubb, University of Cambridge. Speakers: Professor Nebojsa Nakicenovic, The International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA) and Vienna University of Technology (presentation in PPT, presentation in PDF); Professor William D. Nordhaus, Yale University (speech); Professor Daniel Kammen, University of California, Berkeley (presentation in PPT, presentation in PDF).
- The website of the Cambridge Centre for Climate Change Mitigation Research This organisation has a range of resources on climate change mitigation economics.
- Climate change policy
- Economics and climate change
- Climate change mitigation